The Official Journal of the Pan-Pacific Association of Input-Output Studies (PAPAIOS)

  • Open access
  • Published: 02 August 2021

An extended approach to value chain analysis

  • Klemen Knez   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0003-4772-7074 1 ,
  • Andreja Jaklič 1 &
  • Metka Stare 1  

Journal of Economic Structures volume  10 , Article number:  13 ( 2021 ) Cite this article

17k Accesses

11 Citations

Metrics details

In the article, we propose a comprehensive methodology of value chain analysis in the international input–output framework that introduces a new measure of value chain participation and an extended typology of value chains, with the novel inclusion of domestic value chain to address the extent of fragmentation of purely domestic production. This allows for the simultaneous analysis of both global and domestic production fragmentation, the complex patterns of their evolution and their impact on economic development. The main contribution of the proposed methodology is conceptual: it permits the measurement of all value chain paths that pass through each country-sector from production to final consumption, whether the path includes downstream linkages, upstream linkages or their combination. Empirical application of this methodology shows the importance of including domestic fragmentation in value chain analysis: The fragmentation of both global and domestic levels of production has a significant positive correlation with economic growth. This implies that the effects of global production fragmentation must be analysed together with the changing structure of the fragmentation of domestic production to obtain the whole picture, one that might provide important information for policymaking and industrial policy.

1 Introduction

In recent decades, the growing complexity of the division of labour has been reflected in the fact that ever more production is occurring within value chains, both at home and abroad. Theoretical and empirical approaches to the analysis of value chains have advanced rapidly, yet are very eclectic and heterogeneous. The earliest definitions of commodity chains Footnote 1 date back to the world-systems Footnote 2 theory: “What we mean by such chains is the following: take an ultimate consumable item and trace back the set of inputs that culminated in this item— the prior transformations, the raw materials, the transportation mechanisms, the labour input into each of the material processes, the food inputs into the labour. This linked set of processes we call a commodity chain (Hopkins and Wallerstein 1977 )”. In the 1990s, the research programme of global commodity chains was first systematically outlined by Gereffi’s seminal contribution (Gereffi 1994 ) that defined three interlocking dimensions of the research: the input–output dimension, the spatial dimension, and the question of commodity chain governance Footnote 3 . This research period was characterised by moving away from a historical and macroeconomic perspective towards a special focus on industrial chains and the inter-firm cooperation perspective, with numerous case studies on value chains. The global value chain framework emerged early in the new century with the express aim of unifying the previous heterogeneous research (Gereffi 1999 ; Gereffi et al. 2001 ). On one hand, the global value chain approach increased the focus on the enterprise level and merged with the literature from international business and management Footnote 4 , while also drawing from the new institutional transaction cost approach Footnote 5 . On the other hand, the creation of international input–output tables Footnote 6 led to a revival of the aggregated macroeconomic approach to global value chains, albeit with a different focus than the world-systems approach. Footnote 7

In this article, we present a new methodology for measuring different value chain participation rates in the international input–output framework. Compared to the most widely used measurement of value chain participation introduced by Wang et al. ( 2017 ), we make two fundamental conceptual enhancements.

First, our methodology creates a single and consistent measurement of value chain participation on the country-sector level, as opposed to the two (upstream and downstream) participation rates that feature in Wang’s methodology. The argumentation and logic used to derive a single value chain participation share on the country-sector level is very similar to the approach of Arto et al. ( 2019 ), which combines the source- and sink-based approaches to export decomposition. The idea is that decomposition based on final demand (sink-based decomposition) is independent of the decomposition of downstream value added (source-based) and thus both can be linearly combined to grasp both the information regarding the source of value added as well as the path to final demand simultaneously. Methodologies of export decomposition have recently seen significant improvements (Arto et al. 2019 ; Borin and Mancini 2019 ; Miroudot and Ye 2021 ). However, the value chain participation rate methodologies either still chiefly rely on the value-added export matrix to describe the value flows between any two country-sectors in the economy (Johnson and Noguera 2012 ) and result in separate upstream and downstream participation rate measures or combine a sink- and a source-based measure in merely one-sided, forward-looking measures. Our approach to value chain decomposition no longer uses the value-added export matrix and instead breaks down the asymmetric value chain stemming both downstream and upstream from each country-sector concerned simultaneously . Creating a single consistent variable on the country-sector level that measures the overall level of participation in value chains enables the empirical testing of many research theses that were previously either limited to the aggregate level or had to be articulated separately in terms of measuring the impacts of upstream and downstream value chain integration.

Second, our methodology allows extensions of the value chain typology that are not possible with Wang’s approach to the decomposition of production activities or with export decompositions. We introduce a novel measure of the domestic value chain participation rate to measure the share of production which represents the extent of the fragmentation of domestic production. In place of a single and undifferentiated domestic component, we distinguish domestic production, which is fragmented (involving measurable cooperation among domestic firms), and domestic production, which is not fragmented (consisting of producing direct value for consumption without the cooperation of domestic firms). This makes our concept of the domestic value chain a completely new and different concept compared to Wang’s domestic component, which does not distinguish the two and combines both categories within a single undifferentiated concept. While Wang’s share of the domestic component is only a simple residual—a negation of the share of the fragmentation of global production and the global Ricardian trade share that does not provide information about the nature of the domestic economy, our novel methodology allows us to measure the extent of fragmentation of domestic production in addition to the usual study of the fragmentation of international production.

We aim to use our approach to provide methodological tools that facilitate exploration of the complex interrelationship of global and domestic value chains and their evolution over time. We believe this will add to understanding of the diverse patterns of the structural integration of various countries/sectors and the different effects of such patterns on economic development. While this is primarily a methodological contribution, we shall use elementary empirical data to try to show the possible link between the level of fragmentation of global and domestic production and overall economic growth.

The article is structured as follows: In Sect. 2 , we review the existing value chain indicators and address their shortcomings. In Sect. 3 , we present our methodology. In Sect. 3.1 , we present a new conceptualisation of value chain in the international I–O framework and define our object of disaggregation. A new value chain typology is presented in Sect. 3.2 where we also derive participation shares. In Sect. 4 , we present an example of empirical application and some basic empirical results of the new methodology to show the insights into economic structures that can be gained by using the new value chain measures and which links exist between value chain integration patterns and overall economic growth. Finally, we discuss the contributions of the paper, its limitations and possibilities for further research.

2 Background

The most recent macroeconomic analyses of global value chains rely on the international input–output methodology. As international I–O data are essentially an integrated standard accounting data set harmonised on the sectoral level, information is lacking on the typology of value chain governance. This means the international I–O database cannot be the sole source for the study of production networks, which theoretically differ from purely open trade transactions by including at least some level of hierarchy, and which investigate the local embedding of production linkages (Buckley  2009 ; Henderson et al. 2002 ; Hess and Coe 2006 ; Hortaçsu and Syverson 2009 ). However, the general framework of global value chains can function without such distinctions and this makes the international I–O data set one of its most important sources of information. The key benefit of applying the I–O methodology in global value chain analysis is that aggregated information about the structure of value chains can be obtained, as opposed to isolated firm-specific case studies that can provide a more detailed understanding of different aspects of a given value chain. Thus, of the three dimensions of commodity chain research noted by Gereffi ( 1994 ), both the I–O aspect and the spatial dimension, can be considered in the international I–O approach, while the governance aspect cannot. Various aggregated and sectoral global value chain indicators, indices and measures have been proposed, all derived from the international I–O framework. GVC indicators may be roughly divided into measures of length Footnote 8 and participation rates, which we will discuss briefly.

Early I–O measures of the GVC structure were simple upstream and downstream indicators that corresponded to the measure of distance to final demand (upstream) and the Leontief measure of backward linkage (downstream) and were often referred to as the length of a value chain (Ahmad et al. 2017). Fally ( 2011 ) and Antràs et al. ( 2012 ) defined the downstream indicator to “reflect how many plants (stages) are involved in production one after the other” up to the point observed and the upstream indicator to “measure how many plants this product will pass through (e.g. by assembly with other products) before it reaches final demand (Fally 2011 , 10)”. Fally ( 2011 ) defined them as the number of vertical stages weighted by the value added of each stage, with the distance between each stage set to 1. Footnote 9 Since then, the average vertical distance has been the basic measure of the length of the value chain in the international I–O framework. Miller and Temurshoev ( 2015 ) further specified the existing measures by presenting upstream and downstream indicators in a matrix formulation using Ghosh’s forward and Leontief’s backward coefficient matrices (Ghosh 1958 ; Leontief 1936 ). These upstream and downstream measures are simple measures of the upstream and downstream length of value chains measured by the average vertical distance. Within this framework, further improvements were introduced by Muradov ( 2016 ), who focused on separating the domestic from the global production component while calculating the length of value chains.

The existing dominant conceptualisation of GVC participation measures is largely based on the work of Johnson and Noguera ( 2012 ), who produced a value-added export matrix that captures information on value flows in the economy between any two points (country-sectors) in the economy. This provides the basis for the disaggregation of value on the country-sector level, depending on whether the value was produced domestically for domestic consumption or involved cross-border transactions for either final or productive consumption (Koopman et al. 2014 ; Los et al. 2015 ; Wang et al. 2017 ). Since the value-added export matrix tells us about the source and destination of value added and covers all possible paths between any two country-sectors in the economy, there are two indicators of the share of GVC participation—the upstream and downstream share. The conception of the upstream participation share of participation starts from the value added of individual industries (country-sectors), disaggregating all possible paths leading to the realisation of their value, while the conception of the downstream share of participation starts with final consumption, disaggregating all possible paths of the downstream production linkages. Within this framework, disaggregation is defined on the domestic part, the “Ricardian trade” in finished goods, the simple GVC and the complex GVC, which is currently the most widely used accounting framework for GVC participation and thus far has been used by the best-known research on GVC carried out jointly by the WTO, the WB group, the OECD, IDE-JETRO, RCGVC-UIBE and the China Development Research Foundation (GVC Development Reports). Further improvements and clarifications of the framework were made by Borin and Mancini ( 2019 ), who derive their own measure of GVC-related bilateral trade flows by decomposing export to that attributable to traditional trade and GVC trade. Their indicator is composed of source-based backward and sink-based forward parts of their export decomposition, which can be calculated in a bilateral, country and world setting.

The development of I–O participation share measures of value chains, which are the primary interest of this article, evolved simultaneously with the development of methodologies of decomposing trade in value added (Johnson and Noguera 2012 ) as well as value added in trade (Arto et al. 2019 ; Borin and Mancini 2019 ; Miroudot and Ye 2021 ). However, despite similarities and some conceptual and formal mathematical overlapping, the fields of value chain participation share measures and value added in trade are driven by quite distinct research questions and research interests. On one hand, principal interest in decomposing exports is the correct evaluation of cross-border flows (properly removing double counting), assessing trade policy impacts and conducting overall impact analysis, either in a bilateral setting or with a focus on a specific country. On the other hand, value chain participation measures attempt to grasp the structure of an economy, sectoral and country interdependencies and the specific embeddedness of each production unit in different value chain structures, both at home and abroad. Value chain participation share measures usually correspond to a share of production, which statistically satisfies certain a priori criteria, such as “at least two cross-border transactions” or “at least one cross-border production sharing transaction”. The reviewed literature has contributed to better understanding of value chains and their I–O applied research, but still suffers two shortcomings that we try to address and improve with our approach.

The first main shortcoming of all current value chain participation share indicators is the lack of a single uniform measure for different value chain participation rates on the country-sector level. First, the value chain decomposition of Wang et al. ( 2017 ) results in downstream and upstream value chain participation rates, which provide two different types of information at the country-sector level. This is relevant for some types of analysis that deal with the relationship between upstream and downstream participation in GVCs, but there is a variety of situations where a common measure of GVC participation, defined uniformly on the country-sector level, is required either as the main object of the analysis or as a supplementary or control variable. Footnote 10 Second, GVC measures based on the decomposition of exports, even though they overcome the sink- and source-based decomposition in one unifying framework of export decomposition (Arto et al. 2019 ; Borin and Mancini 2019 ), are conceptually unable to offer a consistent solution to the question of a single country-sector value chain participation measure. That is because the criteria for export decomposition (separating domestic value added from foreign value added and the removal of double counting) do not correspond with the general criteria for different value chains on the country-sector level (the share of production with a certain number of cross-border transactions). Although export can be decomposed both with regard to the origin of the value added as well as the final demand, the very fact that the object of decomposition is export means it has a one-sided, forward orientation since export decomposition cannot address the fragmentation of production of a country-sector that has little or no exports (but can still form part of the fragmentation of a global value chain downstream). In this sense, the attempt by Borin and Mancini ( 2019 ) to provide a GVC measure of bilateral trade by decomposing exports cannot identify the share of production of a given country-sector which satisfies the criterion of a certain number of cross-border transactions, but only examines its forward part and is hence conceptually similar to Wang’s forward GVC measure. Our attempt to solve this issue demands the decomposition of the gross output (total output) of each country-sector to simultaneously account for both downstream and upstream value chain linkages.

The second major shortcoming of existing value chain indicators is the lack of a measure of domestic value chain fragmentation. The decomposition put forward by Wang et al. ( 2017 ) includes a broadly defined “domestic component”, which covers all of the value that does not comply with the GVC and Ricardian trade criteria. One of the major contributions of this article is to conceptually further divide this broad domestic component into a first part which comprises domestic production fragmentation (involving production sharing between at least two domestic firms) and the second part which does not. This yields new information regarding the share of production not involved in the fragmentation of global production, but is part of the fragmentation of domestic production and enables research into the role of domestic production fragmentation, which was impossible with the existing conceptualisations. As a result of the present disaggregation of participation shares into the “domestic component” and the GVC participation rates (and the Ricardian trade share) consisting of a simple duality that in its construction sums to 1, the share of the domestic component is never used in regressions (due to collinearity) and never even examined as a theoretical concept. It is simply a residual, a share that does not interest researchers given that all the information they disaggregate is included in their GVC participation rates. The existing approaches are used by researchers to focus exclusively on the international dimension of the fragmentation of production, neglecting the potential held by the international I–O methodology that allows analysis of domestic production fragmentation. Our approach is breaks ground in this area as it proposes a new concept of domestic fragmentation able to be measured on its own and according to its own definition and that is not collinear with the sum of the GVC participation rate.

Our methodological approach starts with the formal criteria, which is common for most of the GVC literature where value chains are defined according to certain transaction criteria (number of cross-border production-sharing transactions or similar). It is important to note that any such criteria are arbitrary and potential multiplicity of such criteria and hence value chain typologies can coexist and offer researchers some leeway in their empirical applications. Footnote 11 With a view to creating a uniform value chain measure on the country-sector level, we use the total output of each country-sector as the starting point of our disaggregation. Decomposing total output (as opposed to export or total value added) enables us to simultaneously grasp both the downstream and upstream value chain paths as well as the structure of the economy that is entirely domestic. Our decomposition begins with a set of the presented value chain tree matrices ( \(\tau _i\) ) which describe all of the value chain paths, from any country-sector of primary origin to any country-sector of production for final consumption that passes through (include a production stage of) a single particular country-sector. The logic of our approach is very similar to that of Arto et al. ( 2019 ) for combining the sink- and source-based decomposition of exports: because the decomposition of paths to final demand is independent of the decomposition of downstream value added, these decompositions can be linearly combined to capture both types of information in a single decomposition along two different dimensions at the same time. The big distinction with this approach is that object of decomposition is different—in our case, it is the total output (gross output) of each country-sector. Our choice of the object of decomposition is a prerequisite for properly capturing downstream linkages and, more importantly, properly accounting for the domestic structure of the economy. This formulation is the first attempt to capture information concerning the asymmetric value chain tree, which is a specific feature of each individual country-sector (Fig. 1 ). The proposed value chain tree matrices are unique in that they allow us to simultaneously capture the structure of the downstream and upstream value chain paths and to define value chain participation rates as a single measure for each country-sector. The crucial point of the proposed methodology is to enable the disaggregation of value chains based solely on the structure of value chain paths—taking into account whether these paths include only domestic production fragmentation, international production fragmentation or no production fragmentation at all. This allows us to introduce the concept of domestic value chain fragmentation that simply cannot be created within the existing framework of 2 separate participation indices. This multiplies the research opportunities offered by the value chain methodology based on the international input–output structure by permitting general analysis of the fragmentation of both domestic and global production and their interdependence along with any mutual effects of their development.

Applying this methodology, we show that increasing fragmentation of global production in recent decades has been a general trend for most countries (with a backlash in later years), but different institutional arrangements and structural economic positions led to various types of global economic integration, bringing diverse effects for domestic fragmentation. With our methodology, we shall empirically demonstrate that in many countries with high growth and ever stronger global integration domestic fragmentation also increased. However, one can find cases where domestic fragmentation stagnated or even declined whereas fragmentation of the global value chain increased. The different types of integration in global value chains are the outcome of several structural and institutional developments. Footnote 12 On one hand, the simultaneous increase in domestic and global fragmentation might only be a consequence of the growing complexity and division of labour. Yet, on the other hand, the simultaneous rise in global fragmentation and drastic decline in domestic integration might be due to the fracturing of domestic vertically integrated companies, parts of which are integrated into global value chains as subsidiaries, or due to the gradual replacement of domestic suppliers by globally traded inputs, which may increase following a foreign takeover or privatisation. The wide range of possibilities mean that every production unit may hold a different structural position within global production as a whole, and different structural positions may imply varying levels of dependence, which can be a factor of economic performance, especially during a crisis (Horvath and Grabowski 1999 ).

3.1 The value chain tree

3.1.1 conceptualisation.

We understand a value chain as a series of stages in the production of a product or service for the end user, where each stage adds value and the total value of the end product is the sum of the value added in each stage. For a value chain to exist, there must be at least two separate production stages. The existing GVC framework is analytically and empirically based on the idea that value is created in the production process and added to the value already present in the intermediate goods being used. The old value (value of intermediaries) is only transferred to the new product, while the newly created value is added linearly to the transferred value. The same idea also lies behind the elimination of double counting in standard gross trade statistics and exploration of the hidden underlying trade in value added, which provides insight into the international structure of trade (Arto et al. 2019 ; Johnson and Noguera 2012 ; Miroudot and Ye 2021 ). We make the same basic assumptions for value chain analysis.

We examine the structure of the economy from the perspective of a small unit Footnote 13 (country-sector) and capture its structural position within domestic and international production by measuring the degree of integration into domestic or global value chains. Each production unit is located within the production structure with a number of production-sharing transactions. On one side, the conditions of production are linked to the inputs produced by other firms in downstream linkages and, on the other, the final consumption of its product may only be reached after a series of upstream linkages in which its output is used as an input by other firms.

Accordingly, if one concentrates on a specific unit (country-sector) and aims to capture the upstream and downstream value chain linkages simultaneously , the value chain can be viewed as a tree, in contrast to the snake or spider analogy (see Fig. 1 ). Footnote 14 In the general case, the product is partly consumed immediately after production but also partly sent on to further stages of production and from each of these upstream stages it is further decomposed in the same way (etc., ad infinitum), spreading out like twigs and leaves until it ends completely in final consumption. Similarly, the primary value-creating activity can be represented by the structure of the roots, whereby value is only partially created in each stage since it requires pre-existing intermediates, which in turn are further decomposed in the same way ad infinitum.

figure 1

Value chain tree. Source: own conceptualisation and design. Arrows represent production-sharing transactions—buying and selling of intermediate products for production. Orange colour denotes production that does not involve any production sharing, while any combination of red or orange paths denotes domestic production fragmentation. Any value chain path which includes a cross-country production-sharing transaction (a black arrow) is part of a global value chain from the perspective of the particular unit in focus. The paths of value creating and value realisation in a general case continue to branch ad infinitum (three levels are chosen only for demonstration purposes)

To conceptualise and measure the value chain structure of each specific smallest unit of analysis (country-sector), we introduce the value chain path concept. From the perspective of a firm, a value chain path is a series of transactions between firms that lead from a value-adding process to final demand. While currently no data exist that would account for every transaction between all firms Footnote 15 , firm transactions still represent a basis for any I–O sectoral aggregation, which can help us detect tangible differences in the value chain path structure in different country-sectors. While it is impossible with the given limits of accounting data to follow a certain value chain path of each specific product of each specific firm, it is nevertheless possible to analyse the average sectoral structure of value chain paths subject to whether the aggregated transactions between firms (and to the final consumer) are domestic or global. Our use of the signifier “transactions between firms” and “production-sharing transactions” thus does not refer to individual transactions, but instead refers to the information captured by the aggregated sectoral international I–O data regarding the average structure of value chain transactions. Since we do not focus on following transactions for an individual product but distinguish domestic from cross-border transactions between production units, aggregated I–O data are a sufficient starting point. While the accounting rules require transactions between firms in the same sector and the same country to be formally accounted (represented in aggregated form by the purely diagonal elements of the international Leontief coefficient matrix), the same goes for transactions between domestic firms from different sectors (represented in aggregated form by the block diagonal elements of the international Leontief coefficient matrix with purely diagonal elements 0). In this aggregated setting, one can differentiate between domestic and cross-border transactions (quantitatively in terms of shares), which gives the basis for decomposing different value chain paths based on the criterion of the number of cross-border or domestic production-sharing transactions. As shown in Fig. 1 , the value chain path can be decomposed with respect to two dimensions: Origin (where the value was primarily created) and the final stage of production (where the end product for consumption is finished).

Our goal of deriving a single value chain participation share measure on the country-sector level requires the derivation of an object able to track the value passing through a specific country-sector in focus along all possible paths from its origin to its end use. In this way, we decompose the value that forms part of the production process of a given country-sector along all its paths, which not only include the downstream paths leading to the country-sector under study and the upstream paths leading from it to final consumption, but also, and above all, the paths that combine upstream and downstream linkages and pass through that country-sector. In general, any value share can originate in any country-sector, and the same value share can also reach final consumption as a product of any country-sector. Compared to the approach of Johnson and Noguera, we add a third dimension Footnote 16 —the midpoint—the siphon through which the value from any origin to any final stage flows (Fig. 1 ), by combining decompositions based on value added and the final demand value chain path. This approach relies on similar reasoning as that of decomposing exports based on both value added and final demand (Arto et al. 2019 ).

The value chain tree of each country-sector is defined as the structure of the value chain paths, where this country-sector is the siphon via which the value chain paths pass. We show that each unit of analysis (country-sector) has a unique value chain structure that represents its structural position in the economy. Its output can be decomposed along every possible path within its value chain tree—i.e. along every value chain path that has its primary origin in any country-sector, passes through downstream linkages to the production stage of the country-sector which defines the value chain tree (the siphon), and ends in final consumption through upstream linkages as the final product of any country-sector.

Understanding the structure of value chains by empirically measuring all such paths of each country-sector (the smallest unit of analysis) is already an end in itself and can help with further understanding of the economy and its changing structure in terms of global integration, its specific regional and sectoral forms, and the complex interactions between domestic and global production fragmentation.

3.1.2 Derivation

The object of disaggregation is a country-sector’s total output. Each country-sector’s total output is disaggregated along both downstream and upstream linkages that are unique to its specific value chain structure. Downstream disaggregation represents all possible value chain paths from the origin of production and upstream disaggregation all possible paths to satisfy the final demand, both with respect to the unique value chain tree of each country-sector. In this way, we disaggregate the same object—the total output of each country-sector—simultaneously along its downstream and upstream paths.

In contrast to approaches based on the matrix of value-added exports (Johnson and Noguera 2012 ; Wang et al. 2017 ) to cover all value-added flows between any two country-sectors in an economy, we propose a new object—a set of matrices that describe the value chain structure of each country-sector separately, covering all value chain paths from each primary origin to each final stage via the output of a single specific country-sector (Fig. 1 ). In this conceptualisation, each country-sector has a corresponding value chain tree described by the value chain tree matrix—while the value chain structure of the economy as a whole is described by the set of such matrices.

We derive our disaggregation within the static international Leontief demand-driven model. C , F and x are the main accounting datasets representing the intermediate consumption matrix, final consumption matrix and total output vector. The Leontief coefficient matrix is usually derived as \(A=C{\hat{x}} ^{-1}\) . The variables with hat are vectors transformed into diagonal matrices, \({\hat{f}}\) represents a diagonal matrix of final demand and \({\hat{v}}_C\) a diagonal matrix of value-added coefficients. Footnote 17 The usual pairs of indices characterising the country and sector of origin ( s , i ) and the final destination ( d , j ) are replaced by a single index for each country-sector for more transparent notation. Since we are no longer working in the \(n\times n\) dimensional space, but in the \(n \times n \times n\) dimensional space, we would need 3 pairs of indices, 1 pair for the country-sector of origin, 1 pair for the final stage and also 1 pair for the country-sector, which is the siphon through which all possible value chain paths characterise its specific value chain structure. Instead, we are working with only 3 indices, one for the country-sector of origin ( k ), one for the final stage country-sector ( j ) and one to characterise the country-sector value chain tree—the country-sector representing the siphon through which the value chain paths pass ( i ). Footnote 18

We start with the upstream part, by using standard Leontief’s derivation:

Definition 1

Upstream output decomposition W :

\(W={\hat{x}}^{-1}(I-A)^{-1}{\hat{f}}.\)

The matrix W represents the upstream output decomposition along all upstream value chain paths. Its element \(w_{ij}\) represents the share of the total output of country-sector i that reaches final consumption as the end product of country-sector j , along all possible upstream production fragmentation paths in the economy. The i th row of W represents the disaggregation of the total output of the i th country-sector into output shares according to its final production stages that account for all direct and indirect paths of the upstream value transfers leading to the full realisation of total output (by being used directly or indirectly by other country-sectors as intermediate productive consumption). Each i th row of W may thus be characterised as a discrete probability distribution. On one hand, the upstream output shares of each country-sector i add up consistently to 1: \(\sum _{j=1}^n w_{ij}=1\) \(\forall i\) . On the other hand, there is a clear economic interpretation of the probability distribution: \(w_{ij}\) represents the probability that a randomly selected part of the total output of the i th country-sector will eventually be consumed as the final product of country-sector j , along any upstream value chain path.

For the downstream part, we begin with identity:

Definition 2

Downstream output decomposition Z :

\(Z= \hat{v_C} (I-A)^{-1}.\)

The matrix Z represents the downstream output decomposition along all downstream value chain paths. Its element \(z_{ki}\) represents the share of the total output of country-sector i that is primarily created in country-sector k , along any possible downstream production fragmentation path in the economy. The i th column of Z represents the disaggregation of the total output of the i th country-sector into output shares, which represent all direct and indirect paths of the downstream value transfer from each country-sector that has contributed to the production of its output (through the direct or indirect production of intermediate productive consumption used by i ). Each i th column of Z may thus be characterised as a discrete probability distribution. On one hand, the downstream output shares of the individual country-sectors i add up consistently to 1: \(\sum _{k=1}^n z_{ki}=1\) \(\forall i\) . On the other hand, there is a clear economic interpretation of the probability distribution: \(z_{ki}\) represents the probability that a randomly selected part of the total output of the i th country-sector was produced by country-sector k , along any downstream value chain path.

The two matrices presented, W and Z , may appear as two sides of the same coin—similar to forward and backward decomposition, which has largely been exhausted in the international input–output literature. However, if we focus on a single country-sector ( i ), the i th column of Z and the i th row of W represent two probability distributions that take the transfers in the value chain into account, which result in two completely different and independent types of information. The i th column of Z contains information on the downstream structure of the value chain of the respective i th country-sector and the i th row of W contains information on the upstream structure of the value chain of the respective i th country-sector. For a given i th country-sector, the two probability distributions are asymmetrical. Most importantly, both probability distributions relate to the same object of investigation—the total output of country-sector i .

Using the total output of each country-sector seems to be the only way to disaggregate the same object into its upstream and downstream value chains. The object of decomposition of the upstream part (which is decomposed based on the paths to final demand) of a certain country-sector can be either its total output or total value added (even its export). However, the same is not possible for the downstream part (which is decomposed according to the origins of its value-added). The object of decomposition of the downstream part of a certain country-sector can only be its total output, which also makes up the totality of value-added shares along the whole downstream value chain. Footnote 19 In other words, the country-sector’s total output is an object that has both an upstream and a downstream path, while total value added and total export represent only that part of the output which has an upstream path, even if this upstream path is disaggregated by value-added origin. Using the total output share as the basis for disaggregating to the individual country-sector level is therefore a legitimate choice. This mainly explains why we derived the W matrix in terms of shares of total output ( 3.4 , 3.5 ) and not, as is usual, in terms of shares of value added—to make it perfectly clear that both upstream and downstream disaggregation have the same object—the total output of i , which includes both the value added of country-sector i and the total value added of the other country-sectors ( k ) downstream. The same object (total output) is then distributed along the upstream value chain paths (as determined by the i th row of W ) until it reaches final consumption along an upstream value chain path.

All input–output analyses assume the homogeneity of the smallest classification object (country-sector in our case). The level of detail of the data corresponds to the level of detail of the sector (and country) classification and within a country-sector there is no further information and quite strict homogeneity assumptions apply. We use the assumption of the homogeneity of production of each country-sector to combine the two probability distributions.

\(z_{ki}\) represents the share of the total output of the i th country-sector, which was primarily produced by country-sector k . Due to the homogeneity of the total output of the i th country-sector, the \(w_{ij}\) represents not only the probability that a random part of the total output of the i th country-sector reaches final consumption as a product of j , but also the probability that a random part of any share of the output of the i th country-sector reaches final consumption as a product of j . Since \(z_{ki}\) is a share of the i th country-sector’s total output, its upstream decomposition is clearly and uniquely defined by the i th row of w .

The product \(w_{ij}z_{ki}\) thus simply represents the probability that a certain part of the total output of the i th country-sector is primarily produced in k and reaches final consumption as the product of j along any value chain path (upstream, downstream or a combination) passing through i . In other words, it represents the share of the total output of i that was produced by k and reached final consumption as a product of j . A simple multiplication of probabilities requires that the two events—a random portion of the total output of i produced by k and a random portion of the total output of i completed for consumption by j —are statistically independent. First, if certain parts of the total output of a particular country-sector were to behave differently from certain other parts of the same output, this would violate the homogeneity assumption, which is the basic assumption of the input–output structure and methodology. Second, at the level of economic theory it is relatively easy to argue about the statistical independence of the structure of upstream and downstream value chains: Nothing about the downstream structure of production in the i th country-sector implies anything about its upstream structure and vice versa . Both are calculated independently and provide completely different information: the downstream decomposition gives information about the inputs produced by other country-sectors used directly or indirectly in the production process of the i th country-sector, and the upstream decomposition gives information about how the product of the i th country-sector is consumed either directly or as part of the final product of other country-sectors.

Two separate vectors which disaggregate the value chain paths of the downstream ( i th column of Z ) and upstream value chain ( i th row of W ) thus span an entire matrix of total output shares that capture the value chain tree structure of the i th country-sector. We combine them with the direct product that defines the matrix of the value chain tree for each country-sector ( i ) by multiplying each element of \(Z\vec {e_i}\) (the i th column of Z ) by each element of \(\vec {e_i}^{T}W\) (the i th row of W ).

Definition 3

Value chain tree matrix

\(\tau _i=Z\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}W\) ; \(\tau _i\in \mathbb{R}^{n\times n}\) , where \(\vec {e_i} \in \mathbb{R}^n\) represents the standard orthonormal basis of \(\mathbb{R}^n.\)

This defines each element of the value chain tree matrix \(t_{ijk} \in \tau _i\) as \(t_{ijk}=w_{ij}z_{ki}\) . Each element of the value chain tree matrix \(\tau _i\) thus represents a share of the total output of country-sector i , which is primarily produced in country-sector k and consumed as an end product of country-sector j , along any upstream and downstream value chain path.

The main point of our derivation is not the expressed final value distribution of the total output of each country-sector along any of its upstream and downstream value chain paths, but the expression of the total output distribution (of the respective country-sector) along any value chain path, be it a downstream value chain path, an upstream value chain path or any combination of both paths at the same time.

The structure of the value chain tree matrices allows us to focus our disaggregation on the composition of the value chain paths covered by the two global Leontief inverses in the equation, the first representing all downstream parts of the value chain paths and the second representing all upstream parts of the value chain paths.

A single value chain path is determined by a series of concrete transactions between companies: It is a unique path from primary value creation (value created in production, not transferred from intermediate products) to value realisation (final consumption, not productive consumption of intermediate products), which passes through the production stage of the i th country-sector. The total output of i is not only disaggregated along all possible paths leading from any country-sector of origin via country-sector i to any country-sector of final stage production (as determined by \(\tau _i\) ), but is also disaggregated in much finer detail, along all the unique value chain paths that pass through i . That a concrete value chain path only forms part of the value chain tree matrix can easily be recognised if both inverses in \(\tau _i\) are replaced by an infinite series ( \((I-A)^{-1}=I+A+A^2+\cdots\) ). Such disaggregation then results in an infinite number of value chain paths, and the total output of the i th country-sector is distributed over all of these paths.

A certain value chain path share of the total output of i is determined by the Leontief technical coefficients \(a_{ij}\in A\) . For example, take a value chain path consisting of value primarily produced in country-sector \(CS_1\) Footnote 20 , then used as an intermediate in \(CS_2\) , which in turn is used as an intermediate in i (the country-sector whose value chain is broken down), and then sent as an intermediate to \(CS_3\) , which is then sent as an intermediate to \(CS_4\) , where it is finished and sold for consumption. This value chain path has an origin ( \(CS_1\) ), a midpoint ( i ) and a final destination of production ( \(CS_4\) ), as well as a concrete path with a length of 5 (5 country-sectors contribute to production from origin to final consumption). The share of the total output of the i th country-sector that may be attributed to this specific path is:

A specific unique value chain path of the i th country-sector’s value chain tree, that has its origin in k and final stage in j , can be written as:

Such a path has a downstream length of d and an upstream length of \(u-1-d\) and the path is determined by a unique set of production-sharing transactions from the origin to the final stage (from origin \(j=CS_0\) , to \(CS_1\) , to \(CS_2\) , ..., to \(i=CS_{d}\) , and further to \(CS_{d+1}\) , \(CS_{d+2}\) , ..., to \(k=CS_u\) ). Leontief technical coefficients \(a_{CS_{p-1}CS_{p}}\) determine each production-sharing transaction. The summation along the total output shares of i attributed to all such unique value chain paths, taking into account all permutations of possible transaction sequences and also all possible lengths (all possible length combinations of downstream and upstream lengths) as well as all possible origins and final stage destinations, results in a unit:

Our conceptualisation allows us to define decomposition criteria applicable to each value chain path of the value chain tree of the i th country-sector. Based on this property, we will decompose the value chain structure of each country-sector separately in the following section.

3.2 The value chain typology

3.2.1 definitions.

The framework of the international I–O analysis allows the separate analysis of final transactions to consumers and transactions between companies. Based on this characteristic, we propose a typology of value chains based solely on the structure of linkages between enterprises, while adding a further decomposition with regard to different possible transactions to reach the final consumption post festum . Footnote 21 Each matrix \(\tau _i\) expressed by equation 3.13 represents the desegmentation of the total product of country-sector i along different downstream and upstream paths. When we refer to a value chain, we refer to the specific share of value (share of output) that corresponds to a particular value chain path. Path Footnote 22 of each value share generally includes any combination of domestic and cross-border production-sharing transactions, which can take place both downstream and upstream relative to the respective country-sector. Our criteria for the value chain typology thus refer to each specific value share corresponding to a single path within a value chain tree specific to each country-sector.

Definition 4

  • Domestic value chain

Domestic value chain (DVC) is a value that involves at least 1 domestic production-sharing transaction and involves only domestic production-sharing transactions along its path.

Definition 5

  • Global value chain

Global value chain (GVC) is a value that involves at least 1 cross-border production-sharing transaction along its path. We further distinguish two types of global value chains: simple and complex.

Definition 5.1

Simple global value chain

Simple global value chain (SGVC) is a value that involves exactly 1 cross-border production-sharing transaction anywhere along its path.

Definition 5.2

Complex global value chain

Complex global value chain (CGVC) is a value that involves more than 1 cross-border production-sharing transaction along its path.

Definition 6

No value chain

No value chain (NVC) is a value that does not involve any production-sharing transactions and has no value chain path within production.

A few brief comments are appropriate on our definitions and their interpretation. No material product or service belongs to a single classification of value chain, and no enterprise can be considered part of a single type of value chain. The output of each enterprise belongs to a variety of value chain paths. In general, one part of the output comprises many cross-border transactions, another part only domestic transactions, and yet another part their relatively complex interrelationship. Each product (or country-sector in our case) can be assigned different shares of the value chain paths. These shares are objects that provide information about the structure of the economy. For example, virtually no enterprise could be classified exclusively as part of a no value chain, but some enterprises that provide services (e.g. domestic services) have a relatively high share of output that has no value chain path, especially in services, where salaries account for almost all of the enterprise’s expenditure and where their product directly satisfies final demand. On one hand, enterprises that specialise in intermediate goods are always part of a value chain, whether domestic or global. On the other hand, even modern industries such as food-processing and pharmaceuticals, also have a certain (usually small) share of value added that is not part of any value chain (no value chain share), corresponding to the share of domestic value added in these industries that is also directly consumed (part of output that has no value chain path). The value chain shares and their changes are the object that provide information about the structure of the economy, whether on the sector or country level. As the economy develops, the division of labour also increases, which corresponds to the growing fragmentation of production, in particular international production fragmentation, and a decrease in shares where there is limited or no value chain fragmentation. Compared to the existing typology of value chains, this revised typology allows for analysis of the relationship between global and domestic fragmentation, which might prove especially relevant for the policies of developing countries.

3.2.2 The decomposition of paths

Our value chain typology is established according to criteria along the entire value chain. For this reason, we disaggregate the value chain tree matrices \(\tau _i\) in terms of criteria for different types of value chain paths. Our decomposition consists of the decomposition of two Leontief inverses, which may be interpreted as the decomposition of the downstream part and upstream part of each value chain path, as defined by equation 3.11 : \(\tau _i=\hat{v_C}(I-A)^{-1}\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}(I-A)^{-1}{\hat{f}}\) . The decomposition is constructed based on of the criteria of the number of cross-border and domestic production-sharing transactions that are consistent with the revised value chain typology.

First, we investigate the decomposition of only a single Leontief inverse (interpreted symmetrically with respect to our criteria in the upstream and downstream value chain) and only then do we analyse the decomposition of all value chain paths characterised by the two Leontief inverses. The international I–O data have a specific block matrix structure in which the block diagonal elements represent domestic production-sharing transactions and the block off-diagonal elements represent international production-sharing transactions ( \(A_D\) denotes domestic—block diagonal—and \(A_{ CB }\) cross-border—block-off diagonal—part of A ), which allows us to decompose the Leontief inverse in the following way:

I obviously represents that part of the output which contains no production-sharing transactions —no value chain linkages. In the upstream part, it represents the share of total output that directly satisfies final demand (i.e. no upstream value chain), while in the downstream part it represents the direct value added of the country-sector whose production is being decomposed (i.e. no downstream value chain).

\(A_D(I-A_D)^{-1}=A_D+A_D^2+A_D^3+ \dots\) represents that part of output which contains at least 1 domestic production-sharing transaction and contains only domestic production-sharing transactions .

\((I-A_D)^{-1}A_{CB}(I-A_D)^{-1}\) represents that part of the output which contains at least 1 production-sharing transaction and contains exactly one cross-border production-sharing transaction somewhere along its value chain path. This can be demonstrated by paraphrasing the part as all possible combinations of a single cross-border transaction among any possible set of domestic production-sharing transactions that occur before or after the single cross-border production-sharing transaction:

\((I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}A_{CB}(I-A_D)^{-1}\) represents that part of the output which contains at least two or more production-sharing transactions , of which at least two are cross-border production-sharing transactions . This logically follows from the fact that parts (1), (2) and (3) cover the total output that contains less than two cross-border transactions, and that the full Leontief inverse covers the total output.

3.2.3 Value chain tree matrix decomposition

We proceed by disaggregating all of the value chain paths as they are structured in the value chain tree matrices. Using the decomposition of the Leontief inverse that we disaggregated in the previous subsection and inserting it into Eq. 3.11 , we obtain 16 components ( \(4 \times 4\) product) for each matrix \(\tau _i\) . Footnote 23 This disaggregation along both the upstream and downstream paths is the basis for deriving value chain shares that correspond to our typology. We decompose each \(\tau _i\) matrix describing all possible value chain paths of the output of the i th country-sector into a matrix consisting of domestic value chain paths only, a matrix containing all possible global value chain paths (as well as simple and complex global value chain paths separately), and a matrix consisting only of the value that has no value chain path.

Definition 7

Domestic value chain tree \(\tau _{i}^{DVC}\)

The domestic value chain tree represents all value chain paths of the output of each country-sector which, according to Definition 4 , are part of the domestic value chains. In Fig. 1 , the domestic value chain paths are marked in red. Domestic value chain paths are defined as all paths that contain at least one red-coloured linkage (representing transactions between domestic enterprises) and include only red-coloured linkages and orange paths (representing the value creation or realisation in the respective country-sector in focus). The first part ( \(\hat{v_C}A_D(I-A_D)^{-1}\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}{\hat{f}}\) ) covers the downstream domestic value added (downstream domestic path), which ends as the i th country-sector final stage (no upstream path), the second part ( \(\hat{v_C}\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}A_D(I-A_D)^{-1}{\hat{f}}\) ) covers the value added of the i th country-sector (no downstream path) that is transferred via the upstream domestic value chain (upstream domestic path), and the third part ( \(\hat{v_C}A_D(I-A_D)^{-1}\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}A_D(I-A_D)^{-1}{\hat{f}}\) ) comprises the downstream domestic value added that is used as an intermediate product in the production of i and then used as an intermediary further in the upstream domestic value chain until it reaches final demand (both downstream and upstream domestic paths). All three cases meet the definition of a domestic value chain.

Definition 8

Global value chain tree \(\tau _{i}^{GVC}\)

The global value chain tree represents all paths of the output of the individual country-sector, which form part of global value chains according to Definition 5 . In Fig. 1 , the global value chain paths are represented by all paths containing at least one black-coloured linkage (representing cross-border transactions between enterprises). Global value chain paths can contain any number of red (domestic) and orange (no value chain) linkages provided there is at least one black (cross-border) linkage along their path. The first element ( \(\hat{v_C}(I-A_D)^{-1}\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}\big [(I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}\big ]{\hat{f}}\) ) covers the downstream domestic and no value chain paths, which have global upstream linkages (simple or complex), the second element ( \(\hat{v_C}\big [(I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}\big ]\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}(I-A_D)^{-1}{\hat{f}}\) ) covers downstream global linkages (simple or complex), which have a upstream domestic or no value chain path and the third element ( \(\hat{v_C}\big [(I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}\big ]\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}\big [(I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}\big ]{\hat{f}}\) ) covers the value that has global paths both upstream and downstream. All of these cases correspond to our definition of a global value chain.

Definition 8.1

Simple global value chain tree \(\tau _{i}^{SGVC}\)

The simple global value chain tree represents all paths of the output of each country-sector that are part of simple global value chains as defined by 5.1 The first element ( \(\hat{v_C}(I-A_D)^{-1}\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}(I-A_D)^{-1}A_{ CB }(I-A_D)^{-1}{\hat{f}}\) ) covers a downstream domestic and no value chain path that has simple global upstream linkages and the second element ( \(\hat{v_C}(I-A_D)^{-1}A_{ CB }(I-A_D)^{-1}\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}(I-A_D)^{-1}{\hat{f}}\) ) covers downstream simple global linkages that have an upstream domestic or no value chain path. These are the only cases that fit our definition of a simple global value chain. A value chain path covering both downstream and upstream simple global linkages already has more than 1 cross-border transaction and is hence part of a complex global value chain.

Definition 8.2

Complex global value chain tree \(\tau _{i}^{CGVC}\)

The complex global value chain tree represents all paths of the output of individual country-sectors that form part of complex global value chains as defined in 5.2 The first element ( \(\hat{v_C}(I-A_D)^{-1}\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}\big [(I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}A_{ CB }(I-A_D)^{-1}\big ]{\hat{f}}\) ) covers the downstream domestic and no value chain path, having complex global upstream linkages, the second element ( \(\hat{v_C}\big [(I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}A_{ CB }(I-A_D)^{-1}\big ]\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}(I-A_D)^{-1}{\hat{f}}\) ) comprises downstream complex global linkages, which have an upstream domestic or no value chain path, and the third element ( \(\hat{v_C}\big [(I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}\big ]\vec {e_i} \otimes \vec {e_i}^{T}{\hat{x}}^{-1}\big [(I-A)^{-1}-(I-A_D)^{-1}\big ]{\hat{f}}\) ) represents combinations of global downstream and upstream paths (simple-simple, simple-complex, complex-simple, complex-complex). All of these elements meet our definition of a complex global value chain because the value in all cases crosses borders for production at least twice.

Definition 9

No value chain tree \(\tau _{i}^{NVC}\)

A no value chain tree represents that part of the output of each country-sector which is not part of a value chain according to Definition 6 . In Fig. 1 , a no value chain path is represented by the orange colour only (any other linkage represents a value chain path). Solely the share of value added produced in the respective country-sector in focus (no downstream stages) and also completed for final consumption (no upstream stages) in the same production phase satisfies this criterion. Since the I–O method distinguishes between a product used as an intermediate product within the same sector Footnote 24 and the product manufactured for final consumption, the use of this definition as no value chain does not depend on the level of detail of I–O data disaggregation. The cyclical effect of the production of intermediate goods within the same country-sector is already included in the domestic value chain tree and, after taking into account all of the defined value chain paths (domestic, simple and complex global value chain paths), a value share remains without a value chain path and with a simple representation as the value added of the country-sector which is also directly consumed. This represents a value that has no path in terms of transactions that represent the fragmentation of production.

This concludes the value chain tree decomposition, which can be written as:

3.2.4 The value chain participation rates

In Sect. 3.1 , we showed that a set of value chain tree matrices \(\tau _i\) represents all possible value chain paths of the output of each country-sector and that the summation along all shares of total output assigned to all such unique value chain paths yields a unity for each value chain tree (Eq. 3.14 ). Namely, we presented a unique disaggregation of the output of each country-sector along all of its value chain paths. In the same way, the summation along the two disaggregating dimensions of our decomposed set of matrices (global, domestic and no value chain tree matrices) captures the overall share of the total output of each country-sector i that meets the criteria by which the value chain paths were decomposed by including either only domestic value chain paths, only global value chain paths, or only values that have no value chain paths at all. In other words, the summation of the disaggregated value chain matrices along any origin and end stage represents the share of output of each country-sector that has either a domestic, a global or a no value chain.

Definition 10

Domestic value chain share DVCs

\(DVCs \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(DVCs_i = \sum _{j=1}^n \sum _{k=1}^n t_{ijk}^{DVC}\) ; \(DVCs= \begin{bmatrix} {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{1}^{DVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{2}^{DVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ \vdots \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{n}^{DVC} {\mathbf {1}} \end{bmatrix}.\)

Domestic value chain share represents the share of each country-sector’s output that has a domestic value chain path.

Definition 11

Global value chain share GVCs

\(GVCs \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(GVCs_i = \sum _{j=1}^n \sum _{k=1}^n t_{ijk}^{GVC}\) ; \(GVCs= \begin{bmatrix} {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{1}^{GVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{2}^{GVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ \vdots \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{n}^{GVC} {\mathbf {1}} \end{bmatrix}.\)

Global value chain share represents the share of each country-sector’s output that has a global value chain path.

Definition 11.1

Simple global value chain share SGVCs

\(SGVCs \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(SGVCs_i = \sum _{j=1}^n \sum _{k=1}^n t_{ijk}^{SGVC}\) ; \(SGVCs= \begin{bmatrix} {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{1}^{SGVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{2}^{SGVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ \vdots \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{n}^{SGVC} {\mathbf {1}} \end{bmatrix}.\)

Simple global value chain share represents the share of each country-sector’s output that has a simple global value chain path.

Definition 11.2

Complex global value chain share CGVCs

\(CGVCs \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(CGVCs_i = \sum _{j=1}^n \sum _{k=1}^n t_{ijk}^{CGVC}\) ; \(CGVCs= \begin{bmatrix} {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{1}^{CGVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{2}^{CGVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ \vdots \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{n}^{CGVC} {\mathbf {1}} \end{bmatrix}.\)

Complex global value chain share represents the share of each country-sector’s output that has a complex global value chain path.

Definition 12

No value chain share NVCs

\(NVCs \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(NVCs_i = \sum _{j=1}^n \sum _{k=1}^n t_{ijk}^{NVC}\) ; \(NVCs= \begin{bmatrix} {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{1}^{NVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{2}^{NVC} {\mathbf {1}} \\ \vdots \\ {\mathbf {1}}^T \tau _{n}^{NVC} {\mathbf {1}} \end{bmatrix}.\)

A no value chain share represents the share of each country-sector’s output that has a no value chain path.

With this, we conclude our disaggregation of each country-sector’s total output with respect to its specific value chain integration based on production-sharing linkages. We can summarise our decomposition in the simple vector form:

3.2.5 Decomposition of the transaction to the final consumer

Since all value chain paths within production are covered and decomposed, we still have one last transaction to the consumer to complete the value chain path from production to consumption. We can decompose the final transaction to the consumer upon the criterion of whether it is a transaction to domestic consumers or a cross-border transaction (export of the final product for consumption). Domestic consumption here refers to the country-sector in which the last stage of production took place and not the country-sector whose value chain we are analysing. Each country-sector has a unique value chain and a specific structure of value chain paths. The completion of each value chain path by a transaction to the consumer can be achieved by an additional cross-border transaction of exporting the final product or consumption in the country where the product was finalised. Such a further decomposition of the value chain paths allows a more detailed analysis of the value chains.

The I–O data include information on the transaction to final consumers within matrix F , which can be decomposed into its cross-border and domestic flows to final consumers ( \(F=F_{CB} + F_{D}\) ) due to its block vector structure. We construct a matrix of all cross-border final consumption flows and a matrix of all domestic consumption flows:

Every value chain path within production can thus be further decomposed with an additional criterion of a transaction to final consumers. Each set of disaggregated value chain matrices, defined by Eqs. 3.16 and 3.17 , can be separated on two matrices, one covering all of the production paths that end in domestic final consumption (no export - \(\tau _i^{NE}\) ) and the other all of the production value chain paths that end with exporting for final consumption ( \(\tau _i^{E}\) ).

Due to their simple additive properties of operation, all of the decomposed value chain tree matrices are similarly decomposed to ones with exporting or with no exporting as the final transaction.

The value shares that are part of each value chain path are thus further decomposed, as explained in Sect. 3.2.4 . The final decomposition of the output is thus a decomposition along each value chain, as defined by criteria that simultaneously take account of transactions related to the production fragmentation (different value chains) and the final transaction to the consumer. A share of value that has either a domestic, global or no value chain has as its final transaction to the consumer either an export or a no export transaction, which provides a detailed decomposition of the participation shares that can be used to construct different composite indices suitable for different research questions.

4 Results and discussion

The proposed measures broaden the scope for empirical application and static analysis of international production and trade. The contribution of our approach entails the simultaneous insight into domestic and global value chains, which allows the study of their interaction and structural changes in economies. All elements of the new typology may vary over time, from country to country and sector to sector and are relevant research topics. The derived participation shares are also simple fragmentation measures, and each smallest unit of analysis (country-sector) is represented by a single measure (scalar share) that covers the extent of overall value chain fragmentation, as opposed to separate downstream and upstream indicators.

Due to the limitations of the paper and its chiefly methodological focus, we present only some very basic empirical results. First, we show the global averages of value chain participation rates based on WIOD 2016 data and the global average participation rates for the manufacturing and service sectors separately (Figs. 2 , 3 and 4 ). Using our methodological approach, we observe that the global average GVC share of world output consistently exceeds 20%, reached almost 24% at its peak before the global recession, and then stagnated slightly below this level until 2014 (Fig. 2 ). This suggests that the most recent estimates of GVCs’ share of production between 10 and 15% (Dollar 2017 , p. 2; Li et al. 2019 , p. 12) may be undervalued. As expected, the manufacturing sector is globally integrated to an above-average extent, with the share in the global value chain rising from 35 to over 40% before the crisis and then stagnating around this level after a brief recovery. The share of the complex global value chain shows the highest relative growth, while the average increase in global value chain integration exceeds the decline in domestic value chain integration. Interestingly, the decline in global integration in times of crisis had almost no impact on that part of the economy without value chain fragmentation, while domestic fragmentation increased almost in proportion to the decline in global integration. Hence, the crisis did not lead to a general decline in the fragmentation of production, but only to a decrease in its global character. For services, in contrast, less than 15% of total output has a global value chain path, although services show some increase in global integration, mainly due to decreasing domestic integration (which may be attributed to the globalisation of business services), while that part of the economy without a value chain appears relatively stable. For this reason, vulnerability to external financial shocks was much less pronounced in services during the crisis.

figure 2

Source: WIOD, 2016; own calculations.

World average participation rates

figure 3

Source: WIOD, 2016; own calculations

World average of manufacturing.

figure 4

Source: WIOD 2016; own calculations

World average of services.

figure 5

China manufacturing participation rates.

figure 6

New EU countries manufacturing.

figure 7

USA manufacturing participation rates. creditSource: WIOD 2016; own calculations

As the data for the world average conceal large differences between countries, we also show the value chain participation shares of manufacturing for China, the USA and the average of the economically most integrated new EU members—3 Baltic and 4 Visegrad countries (Figs. 5 , 6 and 7 ), which reveal structural differences and diverse patterns of development in global and domestic integration. China has on average a high share of domestic production integration (around 65%) and is one of the few economies where the share of domestic integration grew by almost 10 percentage points between 2004 and 2014. In the United States, the picture is reversed, while the already lower average share of domestic integration is steadily shrinking. A completely different pattern is seen in the Baltic and Visegrad European countries, which became EU members in the new millennium. On average, these countries’ integration into global value chains in the manufacturing industries rose from an already high 53 to 69% during the observed period. At the same time, there was a huge relative decline in the already below-average share of domestic fragmentation from 32 to 18%. Interestingly, almost all of the growth in the global value chain share in Central and Eastern EU countries was due to the increase in complex global value chain linkages, while simple global value chain linkages remain relatively stable.

Finally, we use the fact that we have created uniform participation rates by performing a simple between-effects regression to test the relationship between the level of domestic and global fragmentation and economic growth measured by GDP per capita. Since short-term productivity fluctuations can hardly be explained by an economic structure expressed in value chain shares, we use a cross-sectional approach to test the long-term effects of different levels of domestic or global fragmentation on economic growth. Our observations relate to the 43 countries included in the WIOD 2016 data, and the variables are their average annual growth, the average DVC and GVC shares, with the average logarithm of GDP per capita as a control for convergence, the average logarithm of the annual population as a control for the size of the country, and the EU control dummy for potential EU specifics. The main regression equation with between effects is derived in the usual way out of a general panel data model:

\(y_{it}=\alpha _i + logGDP_{it}\beta _1+DVC_{it}\beta _2+GVC_{it}\beta _3+\epsilon _{it},\)

\(\overline{y_i}=\alpha +\overline{logGDP_i}\beta _1+\overline{DVC_i}\beta _2+\overline{GVC_i}\beta _3+ (\alpha _i-\alpha +\overline{\epsilon _{i}}).\)

To ensure a consistent estimator, \(\alpha _i\) must be random effects. \(y_{it}\) is yearly growth of GDP per capita, \(logGDP_{it}\) is a logarithm of GDP per capita, while \(DVC_{it}\) and \(GVC_{it}\) represent shares of domestic and global value chains as calculated by the proposed methodology. The number of countries is 43 and number of time units is 15 (from 2000-2014), making a total of 645 observations in the panel.

The regression results are shown in Table 1 . The logarithm of GDP per capita is a significant variable and negatively related to growth. The result simply reflects the fact that higher GDP implies less potential for higher growth rates, as implied by the convergence literature. Taking this into account, both the DVC share and the GVC share are highly significant variables that have a positive effect on growth rates. Therefore, both domestic and global integration can have a significant impact on economic growth. The same result applies after the introduction of additional controls on country size and EU specifics. Due to the principally methodological orientation of the article, we refrain from a detailed interpretation of the regression results. Yet, it should be noted that it is difficult to separate cause and effect while applying econometric analyses—a country in recession for external reasons could experience a decline in global and domestic production fragmentation due to those same external reasons. In any case, there is a correlation between economic growth and the degree of production fragmentation, whether it is domestic or global. A country that experiences an overall decrease in production fragmentation (domestic fragmentation declines faster than global increases), regardless of an increase in global production integration, might experience a negative impact on economic growth compared to similarly developed countries, in line with our findings. Footnote 25 An increase only in participation in global value chains therefore does not necessarily enhance the growth due to various forms of integration Footnote 26 with different effects on domestic integration, which is also an important factor in determining economic growth. Further studies are needed to examine the relationship between domestic and global fragmentation and diverse patterns of structural integration that could also help in assessing the impact of unpredictable circumstances (e.g. COVID 19) on individual countries, regions or sectors.

5 Conclusion

We have proposed a new methodology for measuring the participation shares of different types of value chains in the international input–output framework. We addressed the lack of a consistent unitary measure of value chain integration on the country-sector level by proposing a new concept of the value chain tree for each country-sector, covering all value chain paths from value creation (downstream linkages) through a single country-sector to final consumption (upstream linkages) simultaneously. By capturing the structure of all value chains in a series of value chain tree matrices, we add a new mathematical object that serves as a basis for deriving the proposed new indicator of value chain participation, which we contribute to the existing collection of indicators.

This methodology allows us to introduce an extended typology of value chains by distinguishing and disaggregating all production activity into the following types: no value chain, domestic value chain, and global value chain—further differentiated into simple and complex global value chains. The most important new conceptual subdivision in the extended typology relates to the subdivision of the existing ’domestic component’ into a no value chain and a domestic value chain. This subdivision, which is only possible with the proposed methodology, provides a better representation of domestic production interdependencies and permits comparative analyses of the simultaneous development of domestic and foreign production interdependencies, thereby enabling aggregated analyses of domestic and global production fragmentation and its interrelated development as influenced by outsourcing or offshoring. Another big change introduced by the new typology is its fundamental production-related character: all distinctions between different types of value chains are made only with regard to (potential) production fragmentation, with a separate examination of the transaction to the final consumer—which may or may not be cross-border. This affirms the concept of value chain as related primarily to the fragmentation of production, while the post festum differentiation is also derived based on the last transaction to the final consumer.

The proposed methodology and typology of value chains provides researchers with new opportunities to conduct future research on different levels of disaggregation, be it comparative geographical analysis (e.g. comparing the evolution of value chain measures between two countries or between groups of countries) or observing the evolution of value chains in different sectoral disaggregations. The preliminary illustration of the new methodology, which attempts to link both domestic and global production fragmentation with long-term growth rates, shows a positive correlation between both global and domestic production fragmentation with economic growth. This result may indicate that it is the general complexity of the division of labour, reflected in the general fragmentation of production, that is chiefly correlated with growth, irrespective of its global or domestic nature. Accordingly, the proposed measure and the new typology of value chains, in particular the novel conceptualisation of domestic value chain fragmentation, could bring to light important information that has been concealed in the existing typology, which conceptualises the domestic component only as a negation of the global value chain and thus did not allow research with explicit questions concerning domestic integration. The complex development of globalisation in recent decades and the shifts of late towards the localisation and regionalisation of economic integration caused by political, economic and external factors make this new approach increasingly relevant. The proposed measure, particularly in conjunction with data from other sources, could further deepen the theoretical discussion and empirical investigations.

In conclusion, we believe that our new methodological approach and the new extended typology of value chains associated with it provide fertile grounds for obtaining deeper insights into different types of value chains as well as a broader set of tools of use for various extensions of research.

Availability of data and materials

The datasets analysed during the current study are available at http://www.wiod.org .

The term global commodity chain is a predecessor of global value chain.

Embracing a historical and macroeconomic approach to the analysis of the global division of labour, the world-systems approach examines the unequal patterns of exchange along global commodity chains as well as different structural patterns of the international integration of the core, periphery and semi-periphery (Arrighi and Drangel 1986 ).

Governance was conceived as either consumer-driven (apparel sector) or producer-driven (automotive sector). This approach was further extended by Ponte and Sturgeon ( 2013 ).

Porter’s (1985) concept of the intra-firm value chain is often used to discuss the specialisation of enterprises, and core competencies and business literature on multinational enterprises overlap with the global value chain framework.

Which was used to extend the producer-driven and consumer-driven governance typology of commodity chain research to a more general typology of value chain linkages, from transactions in a completely free market to a strict hierarchy (Gereffi et al. 2005 ).

In international economics, use of the input–output methodology grew in importance as researchers of various international incentives integrated nationally based input–output tables into harmonised global input–output tables. The most prominent are the World Input–Output Database (Timmer et al. 2015 ), the OECD’s Trade in Value Added and the EORA (Lenzen et al. 2013 ).

While all heterogeneous approaches to value chains focus on a development issue, the recent GVC approach has been adopted by international institutions to highlight the gains from liberalisation and industrial upgrading, while the world-systems approach critically examines unequal rewards along the value chain and different structural integration patterns that may cause the perpetuation of unequal development (Gereffi 2018 ; Taglioni and Winkler 2016 ).

Relative position indices can easily be derived from length measures as simple ratios.

Using a method similar to that used to calculate the average propagation length required for the analysis of the dynamic response to shocks, defined by Dietzenbacher and Romero ( 2016 ).

It is also obvious that a simple solution, such as using the average of existing upstream and downstream indicators, cannot be justified in theory. If, for example, a given country-sector’s share in the upstream global value chain is high (close to 100%) and its share in the downstream global value chain is relatively low (close to 0%), then the average share in the value chain would be around 50%, which is misleading because the value chain as a whole is almost entirely global (using the criterion that the value crosses a border at least once). As far as value chain paths are concerned, despite the small share of downstream global value chain paths, a high share (close to 100%) of the same paths continues in the upstream global value chain such that production as a whole has a very high global share (close to 100%), while the use of the average of the upstream and downstream indicators does not correspond to the definition of the global value chain.

For example, in a forthcoming article we explore the decomposition of value chains based on the criterion of the number of domestic transactions subject to meeting the usual global value chain criterion of having at least one production-sharing cross-border transaction. In this setting, we decompose the global value chain share into a GVC with no domestic cooperation, a GVC with simple domestic cooperation, and a GVC with complex domestic cooperation, offering information on the specific pattern of the EU periphery’s integration.

For example, the concept of integrated periphery was introduced to describe a specific type of integration in the case of the Slovak and Czech car industries, characterised by their proximity to consumer markets, cheaper labour force, the absence of positive spillover effects and lack of domestic linkages (Oldřich and Vladan 2019 ; Pavlínek 2018 ).

In our derivation, which is consistent with most existing international I–O data, the country-sector is the smallest object of analysis. When we refer to our methodology and derive it, the reference to the country-sector refers to the smallest object of analysis given by the level of detail of the I–O data set. If the I–O data sets were built on a more detailed structure at the enterprise level (greatly increasing the dimension), the proposed methodology and measures would work in the same way, with the value chain still structured around the smallest possible unit—in this case the enterprise. Despite the starting point of analysis of value chain structure being the smallest units of analysis, the approach offers many different aggregation possibilities to capture the changing economic structure of production as a whole.

The vertical and horizontal fragmentation of production is often represented with metaphors of snakes (sequential value transfers from one firm to further stages in a linear sequence) and spiders (simultaneous value transfers from different firms to the same company) (Baldwin and Venables 2013 ).

Technically, that would require I–O matrices of a dimension as large as the number of all firms of all countries included in such an international I–O structure.

Formal addition of further n dimensions to the usual \(n \times n\) dimensions.

Definitions of all notations are given in Appendix A .

The simplification consists only of the notation. We retain all the complexity of the block-matrix structure of the international I–O data and remove only the large number of indices, which would make the equations much more difficult to read.

Our downstream output decomposition formally coincides with the output decomposition of the approach that integrates output decomposition with a demand-driven decomposition of exports (Arto et al. 2019 ).

\(CS_k\) represents an index for different country-sectors. \(a_{ CS _1CS_2}\) thus represents a single Leontief technical coefficient indicating that the value produced by \(CS_2\) requires a \(a_{ CS _1CS_2}\) share of \(CS_1\) input.

For example, Wang’s disaggregation into simple and complex GVCs uses the number of cross-border transactions, regardless of whether the value crossed a border for production or whether it is only an export to end users. Such a criterion mixes two conceptually different transactions, leading to unnecessary calculation complexity and the impossibility of further conceptual disaggregation. Existing definitions of the typology of value chains, like all such definitions, are constructed in a relatively arbitrary way. More important than strict adherence to the prevailing definitions is the clarity of the proposed revision and the presentation of the conceptual relationship of the new concepts with the old ones. Our proposal facilitates a more detailed decomposition that will allow researchers to construct an indicator better suited to their research questions. Since the revised typology is based on a more detailed decomposition compared to the currently prevailing typology, researchers can (by simply adding components of the revised decomposition) also replicate objects that correspond to existing studies.

Here we examine the path of production fragmentation, while the path to final consumption, which represents an additional transaction, is analysed in Sect. 3.2.5 .

Details of the disaggregation are given in Appendix B .

This is determined by the pure diagonal elements of the Leontief technical matrix A . Each \(a_{ii}\) represents the portion of the total product of the i th country-sector that requires the use of the intermediate product of the same country-sector in the production process, thereby covering cyclical transactions within a sector. These cyclical transactions are of course included in the decomposition of the domestic value chain and not the no value chain since cyclical transactions represent the fragmentation of a domestic value chain.

The Greek and Italian economies, which experienced the longest recession in the EU during the period, experienced this very pattern (general reduction of production fragmentation, chiefly a reduction of domestic production fragmentation and increased integration into global value chains).

A variety of institutional and structural economic positions brings a range of effects of global integration on the country level.

In the international I–O framework, F is usually disaggregated on the country level as well as in an additional dimension of final consumption (household, government and non-profit consumption, fixed capital formation and changes in inventories), which in our derivation is irrelevant and left out. Disaggregation by countries is relevant for enabling the separation of domestic final consumption and export.

The decimal numbers are truncated on the fourth digit.

Ahmad N, Bohn T, Mulder N, Vaillant M, Zaclicever D (2017) Indicators on global value chains: a guide for empirical work statistics working papers 2017/08, OECD Publishing

Antràs P, Chor D, Fally T, Hillberry R (2012) Measuring the upstreamness of production and trade flows. Am Econ Rev 102(3):412–416. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.3.412

Article   Google Scholar  

Arrighi G, Drangel J (1986) The stratification of the world-economy: an exploration of the semiperipheral zone. Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 10(1):9–74

Google Scholar  

Arto I, Dietzenbacher E, Rueda-Cantuche, JM (2019) Measuring bilateral trade in terms of value added. Publications Office of the European Union. https://doi.org/10.2760/639612

Baldwin R, Venables AJ (2013) Spiders and snakes: offshoring and agglomeration in the global economy. J Int Econ 90(2):245–254

Borin A, Mancini M (2019) Measuring what matters in global value chains and value-added trade. World Bank, Washington, DC. https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-8804

Book   Google Scholar  

Buckley P (2009) The impact of the global factory on economic development. J World Bus 44:131–143. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2008.05.003

Dietzenbacher E, Romero I (2016) Production chains in an interregional framework: identification by means of average propagation lengths. Int Reg Sci Rev 30(4):362–383. https://doi.org/10.1177/0160017607305366

Dollar D (2017) Executive summary, global value chain development repor, pp 1–15

Fally T (2011) On the fragmentation of production in the US. https://www.etsg.org/ETSG2011/Papers/Fally.pdf

Gereffi G (1994) The organization of buyer-driven global commodity chains: how U.S. retailers shape overseas production networks. In: Gereffi G, Korzeniewicz M (eds) Commodity chains and global capitalism (contributions in economics and economic history). Praeger, Westport, pp 95–122

Gereffi G (1999) International trade and industrial upgrading in the apparel commodity chain. J Int Econ 48:37–70

Gereffi G (2018) Global value chains and development. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

Gereffi G, Humphrey J, Kaplinsky R, Sturgeon TJ (2001) Introduction: globalisation, value chains and development. IDS Bull 32(3):1–8. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1759-5436.2001.mp32003001.x

Gereffi G, Humphrey J, Sturgeon T (2005) The governance of global value chain. Rev Int Polit Econ 12:78–104. https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290500049805

Ghosh A (1958) Input-output approach to an allocation system. Economica 25:58–64

Henderson J, Dicken P, Hess M, Coe N, Yeung HW-C (2002) Global production networks and the analysis of economic development. Rev Int Polit Econ 9(3):436–464

Hess M, Coe NM (2006) Making connections: global production networks. Standards, and embeddedness in the mobile-telecommunications industry. Environ Plan A Econ Space 38:1205–1227. https://doi.org/10.1068/a38168

Hopkins T, Wallerstein I (1977) Patterns of development of the modern world-system. Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 1(2):111–145

Hortaçsu A, Syverson C (2009) Why do firms own production chains? Working Papers, U.S. Census Bureau, Center for Economic Studies

Horvath J, Grabowski R (1999) Core and periphery in the world economy: an empirical assessment of the integration of the developing countries into the world economy. Int Econ J 13:35–51. https://doi.org/10.1080/10168739900080027

Johnson R, Noguera G (2012) Accounting for intermediates: production sharing and trade in value added. J Int Econ 86(2):224–236

Koopman R, Wang Z, Wei S-J (2014) Tracing value-added and double counting in gross exports. Am Econ Rev 104(2):459–494. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.2.459

Lenzen M, Moran D, Kanemoto K, Geschke A (2013) Building Eora: a global multi-region input-output database at high country and sector resolution. Econ Syst Res 25(1):20–49. https://doi.org/10.1080/09535314.2013.769938

Leontief WW (1936) Quantitative input and output relations in the economic systems of the United States. Rev Econ Stat 18:105–125

Li X, Meng B, Wang Z (2019) Recent patterns of global production and GVC participation. In: Dollar D, Ganne E, Stolzenburg V, Wang Z, eds. Global value chain development report 2019, pp 103–199

Los B, Timmer MP, de Vries GJ (2015) How global are global value chains? A new approach to measure international fragmentation. J Reg Sci 55(1):66–92. https://doi.org/10.1111/jors.12121

Miller RE, Temurshoev U (2015) Output upstreamness and input downstreamness of industries/countries in world production. Int Reg Sci Rev 40(5):443–475. https://doi.org/10.1177/0160017615608095

Miroudot S, Ye M (2021) Decomposing value added in gross exports. Econ Syst Res 33(1):67–87. https://doi.org/10.1080/09535314.2020.1730308

Muradov K (2016) Structure and length of value chains. Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY. SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3054155 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3054155

Oldřich K, Vladan H (2019) The Czech economy as an integrated periphery: the case of dependency on Germany. J Post Keynes Econ 42:59–89

Pavlínek P (2018) Global production networks, foreign direct investment, and supplier linkages in the integrated peripheries of the automotive industry. Econ Geogr 94:141–165

Ponte S, Sturgeon T (2013) Explaining governance in global value chains: a modular theory-building effort. Rev Int Polit Econ 21:195–223

Porter ME (1985) Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance. Free Press, New York

Taglioni D, Winkler D (2016) Making global value chains work for development. The World Bank, Washington. https://doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0157-0

Timmer MP, Dietzenbacher E, Los B, Stehrer R, de Vries GJ (2015) An illustrated user guide to the world input–output database: the case of global automotive production. Rev Int Econ 23(3):575–605. https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12178

Wang Z, Wei S, Yu X, Zhu K (2017) Characterizing global value chains: production length and upstreamness. Working Paper 23261, National Bureau of Economic Research, vol 51, pp 258–262

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the editor and all reviewers for their comments and suggestions that helped improve this article.

The authors of this article acknowledge the financial support received from the Slovenian Research Agency (research core funding No. P5-0177 and No. 52075).

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Centre of International Relations, University of Ljubljana, Ljubljana, Slovenia

Klemen Knez, Andreja Jaklič & Metka Stare

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

KK contributed the methodological derivations and empirical results, all three authors contributed to the literature review, the discussion of the results and extensive proofreading.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Klemen Knez .

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate.

Not applicable.

Consent for publication

Competing interests.

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix A: Notations

\(n_S\in \mathrm{I\!N}\) Number of sectors.

\(n_C\in \mathrm{I\!N}\) Number of countries.

\(n\in \mathrm{I\!N}\) ; \(n=n_S*n_C\) Number of country-sectors.

\({\mathbf {1}}\in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) Vector of ones.

\(\vec {1}\in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n_C}\) vector of ones.

\(\vec {e_i} \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \({e_i}_j=\delta _{ij}\) Standard orthonormal basis of \(\mathrm{I\!R}^n\) .

\(I \in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) Identity matrix.

\(x \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) Total output vector.

\({\hat{x}} \in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) ; \({\hat{x}}=diag(x)\) Total output matrix.

\(C \in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) Intermediate consumption matrix.

\(F\in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n_C}\) Final consumption matrix on the country level. Footnote 27

\(f \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(f=F\vec {1}\) Total final consumption vector.

\({\hat{f}}\in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) ; \({\hat{f}}=diag(f)\) Total final consumption matrix.

\(A \in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) ; \(A =C{\hat{x}}^{-1}\) Leontief technical coefficient matrix.

\(G \in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) ; \(G ={\hat{x}}^{-1}C\) Ghosh technical coefficient matrix.

\(v \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(v^T= x^T-{\mathbf {1}}^TC={\mathbf {1}}({\hat{x}}-A{\hat{x}})={\mathbf {1}}^T(I-A){\hat{x}}\) Vector of total value added.

\({\hat{v}}\in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) ; \({\hat{v}}=diag(v)\) Total value-added matrix.

\(v_C \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(v_C^T= v^T{\hat{x}}^{-1}={\mathbf {1}}^T(I-A)\) Vector of value-added coefficients – value-added share in total output.

\({\hat{v}}_C\in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) ; \({\hat{v}}_C=diag(v_C)\) Value-added coefficients matrix.

C , A and G have a block-matrix structure \(\mathrm{I\!R}^{(n_S\times n_S)\times (n_C\times n_C) }\) , while F has a block vector structure \(\mathrm{I\!R}^{n_S \times (n_C\times n_C)}\) . Diagonal block elements with respect to countries represent domestic intermediate transfers and domestic consumption and off diagonal block elements represent transactions that cross a border either for intermediate use or final consumption.

\(C=C_{CB} + C_{D}\) \(A=A_{CB} + A_{D}\) \(G=G_{CB} + G_{D}\) \(F=F_{CB} + F_{D}\) \(f_{CB} \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(f_{CB}=F_{CB}\vec {1}\) Total final consumption by exporting.

\(f_{D} \in \mathrm{I\!R}^n\) ; \(f_{D}=F_{D}\vec {1}\) Total final consumption by domestic transactions.

\({\hat{f}}_{CB}\in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) ; \({\hat{f}}_{CB}=diag(f_{CB})\) Total final consumption by exporting matrix.

\({\hat{f}}_{D}\in \mathrm{I\!R}^{n\times n}\) ;

\({\hat{f}}_{D}=diag(f_{D})\) Total final consumption by domestic transactions matrix.

Appendix B: \(\tau _i\) decomposition

We make a demonstration of the methodology on a simple 2 sector 2 countries numerical example. Footnote 28 This simple case of international economy has following intermediate consumption matrix and final demand:

Total output is the sum of all the intermediate and final demand:

Calculation of value added coefficients and Leontief technical coefficients:

We continue with separate upstream and downstream decompositions, W and Z :

Value chain tree matrices are calculated for each country-sector in the following manner:

For each type of value chain (DVC, GVC, NVC,...) we have 4 matrices, each covering all the value chain paths of each country-sector (we have 4 in our example) that conform to our value chain criteria.

The value chain participation shares are obtained by summation of all elements of the value chain tree matrices:

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Knez, K., Jaklič, A. & Stare, M. An extended approach to value chain analysis. Economic Structures 10 , 13 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-021-00244-6

Download citation

Received : 30 November 2020

Revised : 14 June 2021

Accepted : 18 July 2021

Published : 02 August 2021

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-021-00244-6

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Value chain typology
  • Value chains
  • Participation rate
  • Input–output framework

JEL Classification

value chain analysis dissertations

Value Chain Analysis

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online: 11 January 2022
  • Cite this living reference work entry

value chain analysis dissertations

  • Ignacio Llorente 7 ,
  • Elisa Baraibar-Diez 7 &
  • Maria D. Odriozola 7  

521 Accesses

1 Citations

Analysis of value chain ; Supply chain analysis ; VCA

Definition/Description

Value chains are an essential element for sustainable development, not only in economic terms but also in the environmental, social, and cultural dimensions. Despite its interest, the analysis of value chains encounters various barriers, among which the difficulty in obtaining the necessary information stands out. Value chains can become complex and dynamic systems, with different dimensions (company, sector, industry, country, global), and diverse forms, that interact with each other. That is why, in the same way, there is no single methodology or a better methodology for the generality of the cases. There are multiple value chain analysis (VCA) methods, designed and applied mainly according to the approach from which it is studied (firm, industry, country, or global) and the information and time available. VCA in practice should use or combine different methods or types of VCA, which provide different...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Brown, L. (1997). Competitive marketing strategy: Dynamic manoeuvring for competitive position . Melbourne: Nelson.

Google Scholar  

Ensign, P. C. (2001). Value chain analysis and competitive advantage. Journal of General Management, 27 (1), 18–42.

Article   Google Scholar  

Fearne, A., Martinez, M. G., & Dent, B. (2012). Dimensions of sustainable value chains: Implications for value chain analysis. Supply Chain Management, 17 (6), 575–581.

Frederick, S. (2010). Development and application of a value chain research approach to understand and evaluate internal and external factors and relationships affecting economic competitiveness in the textile value chain (PhD dissertation). North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC.

Frederick, S. (2014). Combing the global value chain and global I-O approaches . Discussion paper presented at the international conference on the measurement of international trade and economic globalization, Aguascalientes, Mexico.

Gereffi, G. (1994). The organisation of buyer-driven global commodity chains: How US retailers shape overseas production networks. In G. Gereffi & M. Korseniewicz (Eds.), Commodity chains and global capitalism (pp. 95–122). Westport: Praeger.

Gereffi, G., & Fernandez-Stark, K. (2016). Global value chain analysis: A primer (2nd ed.). Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press.

Hellin, J., & Meijer, M. (2006). Guidelines for value chain analysis . Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), UN Agricultural Development Economics Division.

Inomata, S. (2017). Analytical frameworks for global value chains: An overview. Global value chain development report .

Jones, L., Demirkaya, M., & Bethmann, E. (2019). Global value chain analysis: Concepts and approaches. Journal of International Commerce and Economics , 1.

Kaplinsky, R., & Morris, M. (2000). A handbook for value chain research (Vol. 113). Brighton: University of Sussex, Institute of Development Studies.

Porter, M. E. (1985). The competitive advantage: Creating and sustaining superior performance . New York: Free Press.

Schmitz, H. (2005). Value chain analysis for policy-makers and practitioners . International Labour Organization. ISBN 92-2-117738-6.

Sturgeon, T. J., & Memedović, O. (2011). Mapping global value chains: Intermediate goods trade and structural change in the world economy . United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO). Development Policy and Strategic Research Branch Working Paper 05/2010.

Zamora, E. A. (2016). Value chain analysis: A brief review. Asian Journal of Innovation and Policy, 5 (2), 116–128.

Zott, C., Amit, R., & Massa, L. (2011). The business model: Recent developments and future research. Journal of Management, 37 (4), 1019–1042.

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Universidad de Cantabria, Santander, Cantabria, Spain

Ignacio Llorente, Elisa Baraibar-Diez & Maria D. Odriozola

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ignacio Llorente .

Editor information

Editors and affiliations.

London Metropolitan University, Guildhall Faculty of Business and Law London Metropolitan University, London, UK

Samuel Idowu

Cologne Business School, Ingolstadt, Germany

René Schmidpeter

College of Business, Loyola University New Orleans, New Orleans, LA, USA

Nicholas Capaldi

International Training Centre of the IL, International Labor Organization, Turin, Italy

Liangrong Zu

Department of Economics, Society and Politics, University of Urbino Carlo Bo, Urbino, Italy

Mara Del Baldo

Instituto Politécnico da Guarda, Guarda, Portugal

Section Editor information

Business Faculty, International Business and Trade Department, Dokuz Eylul University, Izmir, Turkey

Berna Kirkulak-Uludag PhD

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this entry

Cite this entry.

Llorente, I., Baraibar-Diez, E., Odriozola, M.D. (2022). Value Chain Analysis. In: Idowu, S., Schmidpeter, R., Capaldi, N., Zu, L., Del Baldo, M., Abreu, R. (eds) Encyclopedia of Sustainable Management. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-02006-4_1129-1

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-02006-4_1129-1

Received : 26 July 2021

Accepted : 09 August 2021

Published : 11 January 2022

Publisher Name : Springer, Cham

Print ISBN : 978-3-030-02006-4

Online ISBN : 978-3-030-02006-4

eBook Packages : Springer Reference Business and Management Reference Module Humanities and Social Sciences Reference Module Business, Economics and Social Sciences

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research

Do a more advanced search »

Search for dissertations about: "value chain analysis dissertations"

Showing result 1 - 5 of 21 swedish dissertations containing the words value chain analysis dissertations .

1. The Collective Action Dilemma in Managing Transboundary Freshwaters : An Analysis of an Outcome-Driven Framework

Author : Jakob Granit ; Carl Christiansson ; Helle Skånes ; Aaron Wolf ; Stockholms universitet ; [] Keywords : NATURVETENSKAP ; NATURAL SCIENCES ; Benefit generation ; common-pool resources ; governance ; management ; outcomes ; regional public goods ; transboundary waters ; value chain ; geografi med naturgeografisk inriktning ; Geography ; Physical Geography ;

Abstract : It is recognised by society that freshwater resources play a major role in economic development and in maintaining life supporting ecosystems services. Transboundary river basins cover about 45% of the earth’s land surface and their governance is therefore of critical importance. READ MORE

2. Spectral Jade : Materiality, Conceptualisation, and Value in the Myanmar-China Jadeite Trade

Author : Henrik Möller ; Sociologi ; [] Keywords : SAMHÄLLSVETENSKAP ; SOCIAL SCIENCES ; jade ; china ; Yunnan ; Ruili ; Myanmar ; Kachin ; borderland ; Ethnicity ; trade ; Craft ; markets ; guanxi ; masculinity ; Materiality ; ontology ; Conceptual ; nonhuman ; Holism ; analogism ; Taoism ; Nationalism ; authenticity ; Spirituality ; Value ; morality ; ethnography ; narratives ;

Abstract : Hosting a cultural history of 8.000 years in China, jade has seen a revival in China’s current era. Jadeite is the most expensive type of jade, and the vast majority of jadeite is mined in Myanmar’s Kachin State and sold in China.Spectral Jade is a study of trade, carving, and use of jadeite. READ MORE

3. Evaluating implementation strategies for improved food safety in Vietnam

Author : Hai Hoang Tuan Ngo ; Johanna Lindahl ; Mats Målqvist ; Hung Nguyen-Viet ; Fred Unger ; Phuc Pham-Duc ; Coen van Wagenberg ; Uppsala universitet ; [] Keywords : MEDICIN OCH HÄLSOVETENSKAP ; MEDICAL AND HEALTH SCIENCES ; Food safety ; Intervention ; Pork value chain ; Cost of illness ; Cost-Benefit analysis ; Microbial contamination ; Experimental auction ; Salmonella ;

Abstract : Pork is the most popular and consumed meat in Vietnam, and the preference among consumers for fresh and “warm” pork makes the traditional pork value chain dominate the pork industry. This thesis assessed microbial contamination in pork, then evaluated the technical and economic aspects of light-touch interventions in improving the safety of pork in the small-scale value chain. READ MORE

4. Method development for the analysis of protein interactions

Author : Despoina Kermpatsou ; Ola Söderberg ; Maréne Landström ; Uppsala universitet ; [] Keywords : MEDICIN OCH HÄLSOVETENSKAP ; MEDICAL AND HEALTH SCIENCES ; MEDICIN OCH HÄLSOVETENSKAP ; MEDICAL AND HEALTH SCIENCES ; in situ ; proximity ligation assay PLA ; strand displacement ; proximity-dependent initiation of hybridisation chain reaction proxHCR ; protein complexes ; rolling circle amplification RCA ; MolBoolean ; vitamin D ; 1 ; 25D3-MARRS receptor ; PDIA3 ; ERp57 ; CYP24A1 ; c-Myc ; prostate cancer ; Molekylär cellbiologi ; Molecular Cellbiology ; Molekylär medicin ; Molecular Medicine ;

Abstract : Biological processes take place through interactions between macromolecules, such as nucleic acids and proteins. It is, therefore, fundamental to understand the functions of proteins and how they form complexes in order to carry out their role. READ MORE

5. Predictions Within and Across Aquatic Systems using Statistical Methods and Models

Author : Peter H. Dimberg ; Roger Herbert ; Andreas C. Bryhn ; Gesa Weyhenmeyer ; Mikael Malmaeus ; Uppsala universitet ; [] Keywords : NATURVETENSKAP ; NATURAL SCIENCES ; NATURVETENSKAP ; NATURAL SCIENCES ; NATURVETENSKAP ; NATURAL SCIENCES ; NATURVETENSKAP ; NATURAL SCIENCES ; Lake ; Water quality ; Chlorophyll-a ; Total phosphorus ; Seasonality ; Morphometry ; Regression model ; Probability ; Markov chain ; Genetic programming ; Temporal-trend ; Earth Science with specialization in Environmental Analysis ; Geovetenskap med inriktning mot miljöanalys ;

Abstract : Aquatic ecosystems are an essential source for life and, in many regions, are exploited to a degree which deteriorates their ecological status. Today, more than 50 % of the European lakes suffer from an ecological status which is unsatisfactory. READ MORE

Searchphrases right now

  • popular literature
  • sampling model
  • in vitro techniques
  • Steel connections
  • hermetic packaging
  • specific radioactivity
  • Big Data Analytics
  • jet turbulence
  • controllability
  • Natural sciences - Chemistry

Popular searches

  • work ability
  • Chemical technology and engineering
  • water resources
  • traffic information
  • spectral domain analysis
  • Flow behaviour
  • information visualisation
  • SPATIAL INTERACTION MODELS

Popular dissertations yesterday (2024-08-28)

  • Perspectives on Inequality and Social Protection
  • CONCRETE FORM[ing]WORK : Design, Fabrication, Simulation and Correlation of Parametrically Patterned Flexible Formwork and Concrete
  • Construction Logistics in a City Development Setting
  • From design to application: Iron oxide nanoparticles for imaging and therapeutics in inflammatory and infectious diseases
  • Some aspects on the effects of dissolved wood components in kraft pulping
  • Towards a systematic approach for technology assessment by combining material flow analysis, life cycle assessment and life cycle costing
  • Disentangling digital transformation : mechanisms of change in institutional logics
  • Microstructure and Fatigue Analysis of PM-HIPed Alloys : A Focus on Inconel 625 and High-Nitrogen Tool Steel
  • Laser induced effects in carbon nanotubes implications for Raman characterization of functionalized systems
  • Competitive Protein Adsorption during Spray-drying
  • Popular complementary terms: essays, phd thesis, master thesis, papers, importance, trend, impact, advantages, disadvantages, role of, example, case study.

See yesterday's most popular searches here . Dissertations.se is the english language version of Avhandlingar.se .

Research-Methodology

Nvidia Value Chain Analysis

Nvidia value chain analysis is an analytical framework that assists in identifying business activities that can create value and competitive advantage to the business. Specifically, business leaders can create competitive advantage through dividing the business into various activities and analysing each activity individually from value creation perspective.

Figure below illustrates the essence of Nvidia value chain analysis.

Nvidia Value Chain Analysis

Value chain analysis

Primary Activities in Nvidia Value Chain Analysis

Nvidia inbound logistics.

Nvidia inbound logistics involves managing the supply chain of components and raw materials into the premises of its contract manufacturers. The multinational technology company performs quality checks of semiconductors and other spare parts using test equipment purchased from industry-leading suppliers such as Advantest America Inc.

Nvidia benefits from the economies of scale in inbound logistics activities due to the large amount of spare parts and components it purchases. Furthermore, the company has strategic relationships with its key suppliers in place and these relationships play an instrumental role in new product development.

  Nvidia Operations

Nvidia employs fabless manufacturing strategy. It employs third party companies outside of United States for all phases of the manufacturing process, including wafer fabrication, assembly, testing, and packaging. [1] Nvidia does not engage in any of these activities directly and chooses to focus the design, marketing and distribution of its products.

The company works with world-class manufacturers to produce its products. Semiconductor wafers are produced by leading companies such as Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Company Limited and Samsung Electronics Co. Ltd, adapter card products and switch systems are produced by the likes of Flex Ltd., Jabil Inc., and Universal Scientific Industrial Co., Ltd. and Fabrinet manufactures Nvidia cables.

Assembly, testing and packaging of products and platforms are done by Amkor Technology, King Yuan Electronics Co., Ltd., Omni Logistics, LLC, Siliconware Precision Industries Company Ltd., Wistron Corporation and other companies within the same level. Fabless manufacturing strategy allows Nvidia to focus on its core competency, that is designing and developing innovative products.

Nvidia Outbound Logistics

Nvidia outbound logistics involves warehousing and distribution of ready goods. Potential areas for value creation in outbound logistics involve delivering to consumers directly without intermediaries, using advanced information and communication technologies, sharing distribution costs with adjacent businesses and others.

Nvidia uses third-party companies to collect ready items from the facilities of its producers to the warehouses of its distributors and re-sellers. The multinational technology company also sells to end-users through its website directly. For this sales channel Nvidia also uses third parties to procure ready products from its producer facilities to its own warehouses.

Nvidia Marketing and Sales

Marketing and sales as a primary activity involve the development and implementation of marketing strategy to increase revenues. Nvidia marketing communication messages focus on unique selling proposition of the brand. Specifically, the software and fables company attempts to associate its brand image with advanced features and capabilities and superior quality. The company also uses the channel marketing utilising its channel partners and original equipment manufacturers to pass through the marketing message to end-users.

Nvidia Service

Service primary element in value chain analysis relates to the level of customer support Nvidia offers its end-users after the sales. The company has more than 50 offices worldwide with customer service desks. Nvidia maintains a dedicated customer service portal on its website where customers can get help with their Nvidia products and services, as well as, contact sales representative about other products. Furthermore, the company has a Partner Locator feature on its website, where customers can find Nvidia partners to purchase from and subsequently these partners are expected to offer superior customer services.

Nvidia Corporation Report contains a full version of Nvidia value chain analysis. The report illustrates the application of the major analytical strategic frameworks in business studies such as SWOT, PESTEL, Porter’s Five Forces, Ansoff Matrix and McKinsey 7S Model on Nvidia . Moreover, the report contains analyses of Nvidia leadership, business strategy, organizational structure and organizational culture. The report also comprises discussions of Nvidia marketing strategy, ecosystem and addresses issues of corporate social responsibility.

Nvidia Report

[1] Annual Review 2022 , Nvidia Corporation

  • Bibliography
  • More Referencing guides Blog Automated transliteration Relevant bibliographies by topics
  • Automated transliteration
  • Relevant bibliographies by topics
  • Referencing guides

Value chain analysis of dairy in Laelay Maychew and Adwa Districts in Central Zone of Tigray, Ethiopia

Thumbnail Image

Date Issued

Date online, review status, access rights.

Tekelyesus, H. 2015. Value chain analysis of dairy in Laelay Maychew and Adwa Districts in Central Zone of Tigray, Ethiopia. MSc thesis in Livestock Production and Pastoral Development. Mekelle, Ethiopia: Mekelle University.

Permanent link to cite or share this item

External link to download this item, abstract/description.

This study was aimed at analyzing dairy value chain in Laelay Maychew and Adwa districts of Tigray Region. The main focus was to describe and characterize different value chain actors, functions and services providers along the dairy value chain, to quantify the economic contribution of dairy value chain to actors and to investigate factors of small holder farmer’s participation in dairy value chain. To accomplish these tasks formal and informal data collection tools for both primary and secondary data. A total of eighty smallholder dairy farmers from Laelay Maychew and eighty smallholder dairy farmers from Adwa district were selected at random and were interviewed using structured questionnaire. Milk and butter were the most important dairy products marketed in the areas. Dairy producers and retailers (café and restaurants) are found to be important milk market chain actors in the study area. From the milk value chain actors, 66.5% of retailers (café and restaurants) and 33.5% of milk producers added a value to the milk. In milk market, milk retailers enjoyed the highest net profit. The econometric estimation procedure was employed to identify factors that determine milk market participation decision and milk sale volume of the farm household in the area. The logistic regression results showed that educational level, cross breed type, access to credit and access to extension service are significantly affecting milk market participation decision. Similarly estimation results of second stage Heckman selection model showed that breed type and total milk product were significantly affecting volume of milk supply. The major constraints of dairy production and marketing in the studied areas were inadequate availability and supply of feed, low volume of milk, lack of training access, low house hold income/low purchasing power, unavailability of cooling facilities for milk storing, distance to market, low market demand of the product, low breed performance, access to transport, land access, access to water. Dairy product value chain in the study area seemed to be ineffective and underdeveloped. Thus, dairy development interventions should be aimed at addressing both dairy production technological gaps and marketing problems. The study further suggested strengthening of dairy cooperatives and milk processing industries establishment, improving access to services and consolidating the linkage among dairy value chain actors should receive due attention in order to improve dairy production and marketing.

AGROVOC Keywords

Organizations affiliated to the authors, investors/sponsors, collections.

Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.

To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to  upgrade your browser .

Enter the email address you signed up with and we'll email you a reset link.

  • We're Hiring!
  • Help Center

paper cover thumbnail

Final proposal

Profile image of Feven Yohannes

Related Papers

Kadigi Ibrahim

value chain analysis dissertations

Asfaw Negassa

Food Policy

Getachew Legese

Euro Asia International Journals

Adil Hassen

Getachew Legese , Asfaw Negassa

tafa gemechu tsegaye

Dirk Hoekstra

Sustainability

Laurens Klerkx , Ashenafi Mengistu Wosen

Based on farmer and value chain actor interviews, this comparative study of five emerging dairy clusters elaborates on the upgrading of farming systems, value chains, and context shapes transformations from semi-subsistent to market-oriented dairy farming. The main results show unequal cluster upgrading along two intensification dimensions: dairy feeding system and cash cropping. Intensive dairy is competing with other high-value cash crop options that resource-endowed farmers specialize in, given conducive support service arrangements and context conditions. A large number of drivers and co-dependencies between technical, value chain, and institutional upgrading build up to system jumps. Transformation may take decades when market and context conditions remain sub-optimal. Clusters can be expected to move further along initial intensification pathways, unless actors consciously redirect course. The main theoretical implications for debate about cluster upgrading are that co-dependencies between farming system, market, and context factors determine upgrading outcomes; the implications for the debate about intensification pathways are that they need to consider differences in farmer resource endowments, path dependency, concurrency, and upgrading investments. Sustainability issues for consideration include enabling a larger proportion of resource-poor farmers to participate in markets; enabling private input and service provision models; attention for food safety; and climate smartness.

Loading Preview

Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.

RELATED PAPERS

Ahmedin Abdurehman

Oluwole Fatunbi , Serge mensah

Editorial Department , Tilahun Kenea

Journal of Rural Studies

Elizabeth Ransom

Rafia Babar

Mohammad Jabbar

Katrien van 'T Hooft , Jan van der Lee

Zekarias Bassa

Ruerd Ruben

Meine Pieter van Dijk , J. Trienekens , Jeroen van Wijk

Gebreyohannes Berhane , Dr. Melkamu Bezabih Yitbarek

Applied Geography

joseph strasser

Berhanu Kuma , Kedir Nesha

Dr. Melkamu Bezabih Yitbarek

Peter Dannenberg

Peter D. Little

George Woode

Yidnekachew Alemayehu

… Research in Africa …

Oluwole Fatunbi

Muhammad Abbas

Research Reports

Mohammad Jabbar , I. Baltenweck , Muriel Figuié , Stella Makokha , Nadhem Mtimet

Sustainable use of grassland resources for forage production, biodiversity and environmental protection: Proceedings of 23rd International Grassland Congress - Keynote Lectures

Ha Duong , Pham-Van Hung , Guillaume Duteurtre , Stephen Ives

Steve Staal

Klerkson Lugusa , Todd A Crane

Globalization and Health

sreemoyee das

Rene Hernandez

Gavin C G Fraser , Ajuruchukwu Obi , Aad Tilburg

Ajuruchukwu Obi

Laurens Klerkx , Catherine Kilelu

CAPRi Working Paper No. 110

Pete Newton

Unlocking markets to smallholders

Aad Tilburg , Jan Groenewald

Livestock Science

  •   We're Hiring!
  •   Help Center
  • Find new research papers in:
  • Health Sciences
  • Earth Sciences
  • Cognitive Science
  • Mathematics
  • Computer Science
  • Academia ©2024

value chain analysis dissertations

Maintenance work is planned from 21:00 BST on Tuesday 20th August 2024 to 21:00 BST on Wednesday 21st August 2024, and on Thursday 29th August 2024 from 11:00 to 12:00 BST.

During this time the performance of our website may be affected - searches may run slowly, some pages may be temporarily unavailable, and you may be unable to log in or to access content. If this happens, please try refreshing your web browser or try waiting two to three minutes before trying again.

We apologise for any inconvenience this might cause and thank you for your patience.

value chain analysis dissertations

Food & Function

Raw and heat-treated quinoa protein protects against glucose metabolism disorders in high-fat diet (hfd)-induced mice by reshaping gut microbiota and fecal metabolic profiles †.

ORCID logo

* Corresponding authors

a National Engineering and Technology Research Center for Fruits and Vegetables, College of Food Science and Nutritional Engineering, China Agricultural University, Beijing 100083, P.R. China E-mail: [email protected]

b National Center of Technology Innovation (Deep Processing of Highland Barley) in Food Industry, China Agricultural University, No. 17 Qinghua East Road, Haidian District, Beijing 100083, P.R. China

c Key Laboratory of Coarse Cereal Processing, Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Affairs, Sichuan Engineering & Technology Research Center of Coarse Cereal Industralization, School of Food and Biological Engineering, Chengdu University, Chengdu 610106, P.R. China

Plant-based proteins have received considerable global attention due to their nutritional value and potential health effects. As a high-quality plant protein, the hypoglycemic effect of quinoa protein and its potential mechanism have not been fully elucidated. In the present study, we compared the hypoglycemic effects of raw quinoa protein (RP-quinoa) and heat-treated quinoa protein (HP-quinoa) and further explored their potential mechanisms using multi-omics analysis based on gut microbiota and fecal metabolic profiles in HFD-fed mice. Our results showed that both RP-quinoa and HP-quinoa effectively improved glucose metabolism and protected against alterations in gut microbiota induced by a chronic HFD. In addition, quinoa protein increased the relative abundance of beneficial bacteria such as the g__Lachnospiraceae_NK4A136_group , g__Eubacterium_xylanophilum_group , and g__Negativibacillus , followed by an increase in short-chain fatty acids and potentially beneficial metabolites such as L -phenylalanine and L -cysteine. Together, these findings provided the basis for linking gut microbiota and their metabolites to the hypoglycemic effect of quinoa protein.

Graphical abstract: Raw and heat-treated quinoa protein protects against glucose metabolism disorders in high-fat diet (HFD)-induced mice by reshaping gut microbiota and fecal metabolic profiles

Supplementary files

  • Supplementary information PDF (474K)

Article information

Download citation, permissions.

value chain analysis dissertations

Raw and heat-treated quinoa protein protects against glucose metabolism disorders in high-fat diet (HFD)-induced mice by reshaping gut microbiota and fecal metabolic profiles

Z. Dai, H. Wang, Q. Shen, Y. Hu and Y. Xue, Food Funct. , 2024, Advance Article , DOI: 10.1039/D4FO02904F

To request permission to reproduce material from this article, please go to the Copyright Clearance Center request page .

If you are an author contributing to an RSC publication, you do not need to request permission provided correct acknowledgement is given.

If you are the author of this article, you do not need to request permission to reproduce figures and diagrams provided correct acknowledgement is given. If you want to reproduce the whole article in a third-party publication (excluding your thesis/dissertation for which permission is not required) please go to the Copyright Clearance Center request page .

Read more about how to correctly acknowledge RSC content .

Social activity

Search articles by author.

This article has not yet been cited.

Advertisements

COMMENTS

  1. An extended approach to value chain analysis

    In the article, we propose a comprehensive methodology of value chain analysis in the international input-output framework that introduces a new measure of value chain participation and an extended typology of value chains, with the novel inclusion of domestic value chain to address the extent of fragmentation of purely domestic production. This allows for the simultaneous analysis of both ...

  2. PDF Research methods for value chain analysis

    1) Strong qualitative understanding of how VC is organized and operates. (can also be a complete piece of qualitative research) 2) Inform the choice of research questions for structured surveys. 3) Support design of questionnaire based on hypotheses. 4) Context for interpreting quantitative results.

  3. PDF Value Chain Analysis along the Petroleum Supply Chain

    2.3.10.5 Value chain and Cost analysis 21 2.3.10.6 Developing a sustainable competitive advantage 22 2.3.10.7 Examples of value chain analysis implementation 23 2.3.10.8 Limitations of value chain analysis 23 2.4 Conclusion 24 Chapter 3 Research Methodology 24 3.1 Introduction 24

  4. Global value chains: A review of the multi-disciplinary literature

    This article reviews the rapidly growing domain of global value chain (GVC) research by analyzing several highly cited conceptual frameworks and then appraising GVC studies published in such disciplines as international business, general management, supply chain management, operations management, economic geography, regional and development studies, and international political economy ...

  5. PDF Value Chain Analysis of Honey: the Case of Dangila District, Awi Zone

    Plant Breeding Thesis and Dissertations 2019-04-15 VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS OF HONEY: THE CASE OF DANGILA DISTRICT, AWI ZONE OF ETHIOPIA ADMAS, ATINKUT ... BDU0906217PR) entitled "Value Chain Analysis of Honey: the Case of Dangila District, Awi Zone of Ethiopia". We hereby certify that, the thesis is accepted for fulfilling the requirements

  6. Value Chain Analysis

    Development and application of a value chain research approach to understand and evaluate internal and external factors and relationships affecting economic competitiveness in the textile value chain (PhD dissertation). North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC. Google Scholar Frederick, S. (2014).

  7. PDF Value Chain Dynamics & Impact of Collective Action on Smallholder ...

    development of these indigenous fruit value chains. Therefore, the topic was changed to "Value chain dynamics and impact of collective action on smallholder livelihood improvement in Kenya". The thesis consists of the following four articles: Mutonyi, S., Beukel, K., Gyau, A., & Hjortsø, N. C. (2016).

  8. PDF ADDISU HAILU

    4.3. Value Chain Analysis 61 4.3.1. Vegetables value chain actors and major functions 61 4.3.2. Enablers and facilitators 68 4.3.3. Value chain map of potato and onion in the study area 69 4.3.4. Value chain governance 72 4.3.5. Challenges and opportunities of actors along vegetable value chain 73 4.4. Marketing Channels and Marketing Margin 75

  9. Dissertations / Theses: 'Value chains'

    Nutrition-oriented value chain analysis has been proposed to support the identification of solutions to nutrition problems, such as low fruit and vegetable (FV) intake. Through a case study of Fiji's FV sector, this thesis explores the application of the approach and aims to identify its strengths, limitations, and potential to inform public ...

  10. University of Missouri-St. Louis

    University of Missouri-St. Louis

  11. PDF Value Chain Analysis of Major Spices (Turmeric and Korarima) in Sheka

    2.3.2.1. Financial and economic value chain analysis 27 2.3.2.2. Input-output analysis 28 2.3.3. Econometrical Value Chain Analysis 29 2.3.4. Global Commodity Chain Analysis 30 2.4. Analytical Framework 31 2.4.1. Value Chain Analysis 31 Value chain mapping 32 2.4.2. Financial Analysis of Value Chain 34 2.4.3. Econometric Value Chain Analysis 35 ...

  12. Thesis: Value Generation and Capture in the Agri-Food Value Chain

    The purpose of this hypothesis is to determine if processors capture the hi ghest levels of value. addition due to asset specificity and their significant influence over the chain. Transformers ...

  13. A value chain and market integration analysis of the cassava market in

    the purpose of this study and because of data limitations, value chain analysis and market integration techniques were applied. The value chain analysis was performed to . iii ... 1.7 Organisation of the dissertation ...

  14. Dissertations / Theses: 'Value Chain Analysis'

    List of dissertations / theses on the topic 'Value Chain Analysis'. Scholarly publications with full text pdf download. Related research topic ideas.

  15. PDF Value Chain: a Conceptual Framework

    Value Chain Michael Porter was the first person who introduced the term "Value Chain' in his book Competitive advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance (Porter 1985). Michael Porter defines "Value Chain'' as a representation of a firm's value-adding activities, based on its pricing strategy and cost structure.

  16. Value Chain Dissertation

    The document discusses the challenges of writing a dissertation on value chain analysis. It explains that conducting extensive research, analyzing complex data, and presenting findings coherently in the dissertation requires dedication, expertise, and time. Students find the process overwhelming due to the large workload, time pressures, and need to balance other responsibilities. The document ...

  17. Dissertations.se: VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS DISSERTATIONS

    Search for dissertations about: "value chain analysis dissertations" Showing result 1 - 5 of 21 swedish dissertations containing the words value chain analysis dissertations. 1. The Collective Action Dilemma in Managing Transboundary Freshwaters : An Analysis of an Outcome-Driven Framework

  18. PDF Value Chain Thinking: A Trainer's Manual

    operation and commitment.3.8.2 BackgroundValue Chain Thinking involves a deliberate decision by chain members to work together to improve their returns by delivering beter services to each other and the type of product t. eir consumers want (Collins et al., 2015). It does not just happen, and it is.

  19. Nvidia Value Chain Analysis

    June 22, 2023. Nvidia value chain analysis is an analytical framework that assists in identifying business activities that can create value and competitive advantage to the business. Specifically, business leaders can create competitive advantage through dividing the business into various activities and analysing each activity individually from ...

  20. Dissertations / Theses: 'Value Chain and Analysis ...

    List of dissertations / theses on the topic 'Value Chain and Analysis Methodology'. Scholarly publications with full text pdf download. Related research topic ideas.

  21. Value chain analysis of dairy in Laelay Maychew and Adwa Districts in

    Milk and butter were the most important dairy products marketed in the areas. Dairy producers and retailers (café and restaurants) are found to be important milk market chain actors in the study area. From the milk value chain actors, 66.5% of retailers (café and restaurants) and 33.5% of milk producers added a value to the milk.

  22. (PDF) Value chain analysis and benefit distribution of Pig industry in

    120 pig farmers, 3 retailers, 3 wholesalers, 12 middlemen, 3 slaughterhouses, 12 sellers, 3. processors, and 12 consumers in three distri cts who were chosen as respondents in the value. chain ...

  23. (DOC) Final proposal

    Value chain analysis considers how and by whom the value in the value chain is captured (Gereffi and Kaplinsky, 2001; Legese and Hordofa, 2011). The analysis of the value chain stresses that the market is increasingly organized through networks linking market agents dispersed spatially in different places.

  24. The future of automotive mobility to 2035

    The rapid pace of change in the automotive industry and beyond is fueling the debate on how to identify future value. In order to help industry players understand these looming changes, Deloitte presents the new "Future of automotive mobility study to 2035", which includes quantitative and qualitative data from executive sessions and interviews, an international customer survey, and a new ...

  25. Raw and heat-treated quinoa protein protects against glucose metabolism

    In addition, quinoa protein increased the relative abundance of beneficial bacteria such as the g__Lachnospiraceae_NK4A136_group, g__Eubacterium_xylanophilum_group, and g__Negativibacillus, followed by an increase in short-chain fatty acids and potentially beneficial metabolites such as L-phenylalanine and L-cysteine. Together, these findings ...